Growth in a Time of Debt

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Growth in a Time of Debt American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 100 (May 2010): 573–578 http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi 10.1257/aer.100.2.573 = Growth in a Time of Debt By Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff* In this paper, we exploit a new multi-country especially against the backdrop of graying pop- historical dataset on public government debt to ulations and rising social insurance costs? Are search for a systemic relationship( between) high sharply elevated public debts ultimately a man- public debt levels, growth and inflation.1 Our ageable policy challenge? main result is that whereas the link between Our approach here is decidedly empirical, growth and debt seems relatively weak at “nor- taking advantage of a broad new historical mal” debt levels, median growth rates for coun- dataset on public debt in particular, central tries with public debt over roughly 90 percent government debt first presented( in Carmen M. of GDP are about one percent lower than other- Reinhart and Kenneth) S. Rogoff 2008, 2009b . wise; average mean growth rates are several Prior to this dataset, it was exceedingly( difficult) percent lower.( Surprisingly,) the relationship to get more than two or three decades of pub- between public debt and growth is remarkably lic debt data even for many rich countries, and similar across emerging markets and advanced virtually impossible for most emerging markets. economies. This is not the case for inflation. We Our results incorporate data on 44 countries find no systematic relationship between high spanning about 200 years. Taken together, the debt levels and inflation for advanced econo- data incorporate over 3,700 annual observations mies as a group albeit with individual country covering a wide range of political systems, insti- exceptions including( the United States . By con- tutions, exchange rate and monetary arrange- trast, in emerging market countries, high) public ments, and historic circumstances. debt levels coincide with higher inflation. We also employ more recent data on external Our topic would seem to be a timely one. debt, including debt owed both by governments Public debt has been soaring in the wake of the and by private entities. For emerging markets, recent global financial maelstrom, especially in we find that there exists a significantly more the epicenter countries. This should not be sur- severe threshold for total gross external debt prising, given the experience of earlier severe public and private —which is almost exclu- financial crises.2 Outsized deficits and epic bank sively( denominated in) a foreign currency—than bailouts may be useful in fighting a downturn, for total public debt the domestically issued but what is the long-run macroeconomic impact, component of which (is largely denominated in home currency . When gross external debt reaches 60 percent) of GDP, annual growth * Reinhart: Department of Economics, 4115 Tydings Hall, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742 declines by about two percent; for levels of e-mail: [email protected] ; Rogoff: Economics Depart- external debt in excess of 90 percent of GDP, ment,( 216 Littauer Center, Harvard) University, Cambridge growth rates are roughly cut in half. We are not MA 02138–3001 e-mail: [email protected] . The ( ) in a position to calculate separate total exter- authors would like to thank Olivier Jeanne and Vincent R. nal debt thresholds as opposed to public debt Reinhart for helpful comments. ( 1 thresholds for advanced countries. The avail- In this paper “public debt” refers to gross central ) government debt. “Domestic public debt” is government able time-series is too recent, beginning only in debt issued under domestic legal jurisdiction. Public debt 2000. We do note, however, that external debt does not include debts carrying a government guarantee. levels in advanced countries now average nearly Total gross external debt includes the external debts of all branches of government as well as private debt that is issued 200 percent of GDP, with external debt levels by domestic private entities under a foreign jurisdiction. being particularly high across Europe. 2 Reinhart and Rogoff 2009a, b demonstrate that the ( ) The focus of this paper is on the longer term aftermath of a deep financial crisis typically involves a macroeconomic implications of much higher protracted period of macroeconomic adjustment, particu- larly in employment and housing prices. On average, public public and external debt. The final section, how- debt rose by more than 80 percent within three years after ever, summarizes the historical experience of a crisis. the United States in dealing with private sector 573 574 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2010 Debt GDP This general rise in public indebtedness stands in 2007 100 100 150 200 250 / = 2009 stark contrast to the 2003–2006 period of pub- Iceland 69 lic deleveraging in many countries and owes to Ireland 44 UK 72 direct bailout costs in some countries, the adop- Spain 42 tion of stimulus packages to deal with the global US 175.1 84 recession in many countries, and marked declines Crisis country average increase of 75% 62 ( ) Norway in government revenues that have hit advanced Australia 22 and emerging market economies alike. China 9 21 Thailand 29 Mexico II. Debt, Growth, and Inflation 25 Malaysia 47 Greece 119 The nonlinear effect of debt on growth is Canada 47 Austria reminiscent of “debt intolerance” Reinhart, 62 ( Chile Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano 2003 and 4 Germany ) 44 presumably is related to a nonlinear response Japan 182 Brazil of market interest rates as countries reach debt 46 Korea 32 tolerance limits. Sharply rising interest rates, India 41 in turn, force painful fiscal adjustment in the Average for others 120 increase of 20% ( ) 49 form of tax hikes and spending cuts, or, in some cases, outright default. As for inflation, Figure 1. Cumulative Increase in Real Public Debt an obvious connection stems from the fact that Since 2007, Selected Countries unanticipated high inflation can reduce the real cost of servicing the debt. Of course, the Note: Unless otherwise noted these figures are for central efficacy of the inflation channel is quite sen- government debt deflated by consumer prices. sitive to the maturity structure of the debt. In Sources: Prices and nominal GDP from International principle, the manner in which debt builds up Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook. For a complete can be important. For example, war debts are listing of sources for government debt, see Reinhart and Rogoff 2009b . arguably less problematic for future growth ( ) and inflation than large debts that are accu- mulated in peacetime. Postwar growth tends to be high as wartime allocation of manpower deleveraging of debts, normal after a financial and resources funnels to the civilian economy. crisis. Not surprisingly, such episodes are asso- Moreover, high wartime government spending, ciated with very slow growth and deflation. typically the cause of the debt buildup, comes to a natural close as peace returns. In contrast, I. The 2007–2009 Global Buildup in Public Debt a peacetime debt explosion often reflects unsta- ble political economy dynamics that can persist Figure 1 illustrates the increase in inflation- for very long periods. adjusted public debt that has occurred( since Here we will not attempt to determine the gen- 2007. For) the five countries with systemic finan- esis of debt buildups but instead simply look at cial crises Iceland, Ireland, Spain, the United their connection to average and median growth Kingdom, and( the United States , average debt and inflation outcomes. This may lead us, if any- levels are up by about 75 percent, well) on track to thing, to understate the adverse growth implica- reach or surpass the three year 86 percent bench- tions of debt burdens arising out of the current mark that Reinhart and Rogoff 2009a,b , find crisis, which was clearly a peacetime event. for earlier deep postwar financial( crises. )Even in countries that did not experience a major finan- cial crisis, debt rose by an average of about 20 percent in real terms between 2007 and 2009.3 debt are not available for many countries. Of course, the true run-up in debt is significantly larger than stated here, at least on a present value actuarial basis, due to the exten- sive government guarantees that have been conferred on the 3 Our focus on gross central government debt owes to financial sector in the crisis countries and elsewhere, where the fact that time series of broader measures of government for example deposit guarantees were raised in 2008. VOL. 100 NO. 2 Growth in A Time Of Debt 575 5.0 6 above 90 percent very high . The bars in Figure GDP growth bars, left axis ( ) ( ) 2 show average and median GDP growth for 5.5 each of the four debt categories. Note that of the 4.0 1,186 annual observations, there are a significant number in each category, including 96 above 90 Inflation 5 line, right axis percent. Recent observations in that top bracket ( ) ( 3.0 come from Belgium, Greece, Italy, and Japan. 4.5 From the figure, it is evident that there is no) n obvious link between debt and growth until pub- o i GDP growth t a 2.0 4 l f lic debt reaches a threshold of 90 percent. The n I observations with debt to GDP over 90 percent 3.5 have median growth roughly 1 percent lower than 1.0 the lower debt burden groups and mean levels of growth almost 4 percent lower. Using lagged 3 debt does not dramatically change( the picture. ) 0.0 The line in Figure 2 plots the median inflation for Average Median Average Median Average Median Average Median 2.5 the different debt groupings—which makes plain Debt GDP Debt GDP Debt GDP Debt GDP / / / / below 30% 30 to 60% 60 to 90% above 90% that there is no apparent pattern of simultaneous 1.0 2 rising inflation and debt.
Recommended publications
  • Bessemer Trust a Closer Look Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World
    Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World A Closer Look. Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World. In Brief. • U.S. and other developed economy debt levels are elevated relative to history, sparking questions over the sustainability of the debt and governments’ ability to continue spending to combat the economic impact of the novel coronavirus. • The U.S. post-crisis experience has the potential to differ from that of Japan’s after the 1990s banking crisis as a result of markedly different banking systems. JP Coviello • A post World War II style deleveraging in the U.S. seems less likely given growth Senior Investment dynamics; current labor, capital, productivity, and spending trends are obstacles to Strategist. such a swift deleveraging. • Unprecedented fiscal and monetary support in the wake of COVID-19 creates many questions about how governments can finance large spending programs over longer time horizons. • While the coordinated fiscal and monetary response to the crisis includes aspects of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), a full implementation remains unlikely. However, a review of the theory can be instructive in thinking about these issues and possible policy responses. Governments and central banks around the world have deployed massive amounts of stimulus in Peter Hayward an effort to cushion economies from the devastating effects of the COVID-19 pandemic. Clients, Assistant Portfolio understandably, are concerned about what this could imply over the longer term from a debt and Manager, Fixed Income. deficit perspective. While humanitarian issues are the top priority in a crisis, and spending more now likely means spending less in the future, the financing of these expansionary policies must be considered.
    [Show full text]
  • Drastic Times Page 1 of 3 Economist.Com 1/8/2009
    Economist.com Page 1 of 3 Economics focus Drastic times Jan 8th 2009 From The Economist print edition Past crises inspire little confidence about the outcome of this one for America THE good news, said Alan Blinder of Princeton University to a crowded hall on the opening day of this year’s gathering of the American Economic Association (AEA) in San Francisco, is that the stockmarket rallied yesterday. The bad news, he joked, is that it bounced on hopes that the economy’s problems would be solved at the AEA meetings. No such luck. The prevailing mood at this year’s event was one of despair, not hope. The tone of the three-day conference, which ran between January 3rd and 5th, was set on its first morning when Kenneth Rogoff of Harvard University outlined the results of new research conducted with Carmen Reinhart of the University of Maryland. The paper*, a sequel to work presented at the 2008 conference, looks at the aftermath of past financial meltdowns to gauge just how bad America’s recession might be. The analysis is based on 14 “severe” banking busts, including the Depression as well as the more recent “big- five” crises in the rich world—Spain in the late 1970s, Norway in 1987, and Finland, Japan and Sweden in the early 1990s. The sample also includes seven emerging-market crises that were left out of the earlier analysis for fear of appearing too alarmist. A year on, the authors have no such qualms. The hubristic belief in America that “we don’t have financial crises” is now obviously false, said Mr Rogoff.
    [Show full text]
  • Medium and Long-Term Scenarios for Global Growth and Imbalances
    OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2012/1 © OECD 2012 Chapter 4 MEDIUM AND LONG-TERM SCENARIOS FOR GLOBAL GROWTH AND IMBALANCES 191 4. MEDIUM AND LONG-TERM SCENARIOS FOR GLOBAL GROWTH AND IMBALANCES Introduction and summary This chapter considers Many countries face a long period of adjustment to erase the legacies long-term prospects and of the crisis, particularly high unemployment, excess capacity and large risks for the world economy fiscal imbalances. Further ahead, demographic changes, including ageing, and fundamental forces of economic convergence will bring about massive shifts in the composition of global GDP. To illustrate the nature and scale of some of the policy challenges posed by these developments, this chapter describes medium and long-term scenarios for OECD and non-OECD G20 countries using a new modelling framework to extend the short-term projections described in Chapters 1 to 3. This framework focuses on the interaction between technological progress, demographic change, fiscal adjustment, current account imbalances and structural policies. The scenarios suggest that gradual but ambitious fiscal consolidation and structural reforms could bring about substantial gains in growth as well as reducing a range of risks, particularly by reducing large fiscal and current account imbalances. The key findings are: The main conclusions are: The next 40 years will G Growth of the present non-OECD economies will continue to outpace see major changes in the that of the present OECD countries, driven primarily by catch-up in relative size of economies… multi-factor productivity, but the difference will likely narrow substantially over coming decades. From over 7% per year on average over the last decade, non-OECD growth may decline to around 5% in the 2020s and to about half that by the 2040s.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Effects of Total Debt and GDP: a Time-Series Analysis of the United States
    Dynamic Effects of Total Debt and GDP: A Time-Series Analysis of the United States Economics Master's thesis Patrizio Lainà 2011 Department of Economics Aalto University School of Economics ABSTRACT The purpose of the present thesis is to examine the dynamic interactions between total debt and GDP. In particular, the growth rates are studied in real terms. Total debt is defined as the sum of credit market liabilities of household, business, financial, foreign, federal government, state gov- ernment and local government sectors. The methodology of this study is based on time-series regression analysis, in which a structural VAR model is estimated. Then, the dynamic interactions are studied with Granger causality tests, impulse response functions and forecast error variance decompositions. The data is based on the United States from 1959 to 2010 and it is organized quarterly. The main finding of this study is that real total debt growth affects real GDP growth, but there is no feedback from real GDP growth to real total debt growth. The response of real GDP growth to a shock in real total debt growth seems to be transitory, but the level effect might be persistent. In both cases the effect is in the same direction. Thus, a positive shock in the growth rate of real total debt has a transitory positive effect on real GDP growth rate, but may have a persistent positive ef- fect on the level of real GDP. The results of this study imply that economic growth typically requires accumulating total debt. In other words, economic growth is very difficult to achieve when total debt is reduced.
    [Show full text]
  • Interest-Rate-Growth Differentials and Government Debt Dynamics
    From: OECD Journal: Economic Studies Access the journal at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/19952856 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics David Turner, Francesca Spinelli Please cite this article as: Turner, David and Francesca Spinelli (2012), “Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2012/1. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_studies-2012-5k912k0zkhf8 This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. OECD Journal: Economic Studies Volume 2012 © OECD 2013 Interest-rate-growth differentials and government debt dynamics by David Turner and Francesca Spinelli* The differential between the interest rate paid to service government debt and the growth rate of the economy is a key concept in assessing fiscal sustainability. Among OECD economies, this differential was unusually low for much of the last decade compared with the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s. This article investigates the reasons behind this profile using panel estimation on selected OECD economies as means of providing some guidance as to its future development. The results suggest that the fall is partly explained by lower inflation volatility associated with the adoption of monetary policy regimes credibly targeting low inflation, which might be expected to continue. However, the low differential is also partly explained by factors which are likely to be reversed in the future, including very low policy rates, the “global savings glut” and the effect which the European Monetary Union had in reducing long-term interest differentials in the pre-crisis period.
    [Show full text]
  • The Pitfalls of External Dependence: Greece, 1829-2015
    BPEA Conference Draft, September 10-11, 2015 The pitfalls of external dependence: Greece, 1829-2015 Carmen M. Reinhart, Harvard University and NBER Christoph Trebesch, University of Munich and CESifo DO NOT DISTRIBUTE – EMBARGOED UNTIL 1:00 PM EST ON 9/10/2015 This draft: September 5, 2015 The Pitfalls of External Dependence: Greece, 1829-2015 Carmen M. Reinhart (Harvard University and NBER) Christoph Trebesch (University of Munich and CESifo) Abstract Two centuries of Greek debt crises highlight the pitfalls of relying on external financing. Since its independence in 1829, the Greek government has defaulted four times on its external creditors, and it was bailed out in each crisis. We show that cycles of external crises and dependence are a perennial theme of Greek modern history – with repeating patterns: prior to the default, there is a period of heavy borrowing from foreign private creditors. As repayment difficulties arise, foreign governments step in, help to repay the private creditors, and demand budget cuts and adjustment programs as a condition for the official bailout loans. Political interference from abroad mounts and a prolonged episode of debt overhang and financial autarky follows. At present, there is considerable evidence to suggest that a substantial haircut on external debt is needed to restore the economic viability of the country. Even with that, a policy priority for Greece is to reorient, to the extent possible, towards domestic sources of funding. *We wish to thank the Josefin Meyer, Michael Papaioannou, Vincent Reinhart, David Romer, and Julian Schumacher for helpful comments and Jochen Andritzky and Stellios Makrydakis for sharing the data from their studies, which we cite here.
    [Show full text]
  • Unfinished Business in the International Dialogue on Debt
    CEPAL REVIEW 81 65 Unfinished business in the international dialogue on debt Barry Herman Chief, Policy Analysis and Development, From November 2001 to April 2003, the International Financing for Development Office, Monetary Fund grappled with a radical proposal, the Department of Economic Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism, for handling the and Social Affairs, United Nations external debt of insolvent governments of developing and [email protected] transition economies. That proposal was rejected, but new “collective action clauses” that address some of the difficulties in restructuring bond debt are being introduced. In addition, IMF is developing a pragmatic and eclectic approach to assessing debt sustainability that can be useful to governments and creditors. However, many of the problems in restructuring sovereign debt remain and this paper suggests both specific reforms and modalities for considering them. DECEMBER 2003 66 CEPAL REVIEW 81 • DECEMBER 2003 I Introduction A new sense of calm descended on the international international financial markets and government issuers markets for emerging-economy debt in mid-2003. The alike have accepted them. They address certain concerns calm was seen in rising international market prices of about how the external bond debt of crisis countries is sovereign bonds of emerging economies in the first half restructured, although some market participants of the year and good sales of new bond issues, in discount the likelihood that those concerns were any particular those of Brazil and Mexico, as well as the more than theoretical difficulties. This paper will argue successful completion of Uruguay’s bond exchange that the changes that were adopted leave unresolved offer.
    [Show full text]
  • Solutions for Developing-Country External Debt: Insolvency Or Forgiveness
    Law and Business Review of the Americas Volume 13 Number 4 Article 6 2007 Solutions for Developing-Country External Debt: Insolvency or Forgiveness Agasha Mugasha Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra Recommended Citation Agasha Mugasha, Solutions for Developing-Country External Debt: Insolvency or Forgiveness, 13 LAW & BUS. REV. AM. 859 (2007) https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra/vol13/iss4/6 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at SMU Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law and Business Review of the Americas by an authorized administrator of SMU Scholar. For more information, please visit http://digitalrepository.smu.edu. SOLUTIONS FOR DEVELOPING-COUNTRY EXTERNAL DEBT: INSOLVENCY OR FORGIVENESS? Agasha Mugasha* The rich rule over the poor, and the borrower is servant to the lender. Proverbs 22:71 I. INTRODUCTION EVELOPING-country external debt is an economic, social, and political issue. The debt weighs heavily on the shoulders of the debtor nations, crippling their domestic social and economic pro- grams, as well as preventing them from participating effectively in inter- national activities such as trade. Individuals and families in these countries are deprived of even the most basic elements of living. The debt problem also affects the rich/creditor nations as developing coun- tries with stagnating or crippled economies cannot be effective trading partners. Furthermore, the social and economic strife caused by the crip- pling debt has a domino knock-down effect on the richer nations. 2 The debt problem has been around continuously for over thirty years.
    [Show full text]
  • Coping with Disasters
    KIEL WORKING PAPER Coping with Disasters: Two Centuries of International Official Lending No. 2157 June 2020 Sebastia n Horn, Carmen Reinhart and Christoph Trebesch Kiel Institute for the World Economy ISSN 1862 –1155 KIEL WORKING PAPER NO. 2157| JUNE 2020 ABSTRACT COPING WITH DISASTERS: TWO CENTURIES OF INTERNATIONAL OFFICIAL LENDING Sebastian Horn, Carmen Reinhart and Christoph Trebesch This draft: June 9, 20201 Official (government-to-government) lending is much larger than commonly known, often surpassing total private cross-border capital flows, especially during disasters such as wars, financial crises and natural catastrophes. We assemble the first comprehensive long-run dataset of official international lending, covering 230,000 loans, grants and guarantees extended by governments, central banks, and multilateral institutions in the period 1790-2015. Historically, wars have been the main catalyst of government-to-government transfers. The scale of official credits granted in and around WW1 and WW2 was particularly large, easily surpassing the scale of total international bailout lending after the 2008 crash. During peacetime, development finance and financial crises are the main drivers of official cross-border finance, with official flows often stepping in when private flows retrench. In line with the predictions of recent theoretical contributions, we find that official lending increases with the degree of economic integration. In crises and disasters, governments help those countries to which they have greater trade and banking exposure, hoping to reduce the collateral damage to their own economies. Since the 2000s, official finance has made a sharp comeback, largely due to the rise of China as an international creditor and the return of central bank cross-border lending in times of stress, this time in the form of swap lines.
    [Show full text]
  • National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model
    NATIONAL DEBT IN A NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH MODEL By PETER A. DIAMOND* This paper contains a model designed to serve two purposes, to examine long-run competitive equilibrium in a growth model and then to explore the effects on this equilibrium of government debt. Samuel- son [8] has examined the determination of interest rates in a single- commodity world without durable goods. In such an economy, interest rates are determined by consumption loans between individuals of different ages. By introducing production employing a durable capital good into this model, one can examine the case where individuals pro- vide for their retirement years by lending to entrepreneurs. After de- scribing alternative long-run equilibria available to a centrally planned economy, the competitive solution is described. In this economy, which has an infinitely long life, it is seen that, despite the absence of all the usual sources of inefficiency, the competitive solution can be inefficient. Modigliani [4] has explored the effects of the existence of govern- ment debt in an aggregate growth model. By introducing a government which issues debt and levies taxes to finance interest payments into the model described in the first part, it is possible to re-examine his conclusions in a model where consumption decisions are made indi- vidually, where taxes to finance the debt are included in the analysis, and where the changes in output arising from changes in the capital stock are explicitly acknowledged. It is seen that in the "normal" case external debt reduces the utility of an individual living in long-run equilibrium. Surprisingly, internal debt is seen to cause an even larger decline in this utility level.
    [Show full text]
  • External Debt, Budget Deficits and Disequilibrium Exchange Rates*
    Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/externaldebtbudgOOdorn working paper department of economics /EXTEMAL 3)EBT, BUDGET DEFICITS EATES^ AUD DISEQUILIBRIUK EXC3A5GE Rudiger Dornbusch M.I.T. Working Paper #547 T < naA massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 EXTERNAL DEBT, BUDGET DEFICITS AHD DISEQFILIBRIDM EXCHANGE EATES^ Rudiger Dornbusch M.I.T. Working Paper #347 June 1984 Revised, June 1984 EXTERNAL DEBT, BUDGET DEFICITS AND DISEQUILIBRIUM EXCHANGE RATES* Rudiger Dornbusch Massachusetts Institute of Tec±inology This paper explores the role of disequilibrium exchange rates and budget deficits in promoting external indebtedness and the current debt crisis. Oil, U.S. interest rates and the 1981-82 world recession are often isolated as the chief causes of the world debt crisis. But these factors have only made much more apparent and unsustainable an underlying disequilibrium in which exchange rate overvaluation and/or budget deficits were perpetuated by continuing and excessive recourse to the world capital market. Ihe details of the disequilibrium differ, however, quite a bit between countries. For that reason we look at three different episodes: Argentina, Chile and Brazil. In one case capital flight plays a key role in the growth in debt, in the other cases the level and composition of spending assume primary importance. We investigate these determinants to the period 1978-82. Ihe pe''iod is chosen to coincide with major changes in the world economy and with disequilibrium real exchange rate policies in several countries. We start by laying out a framework and some facts concerning the debt accumulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Debt and Financial Crises: Theory and Historical Evidence
    SOVEREIGN DEBT AND FINANCIAL CRISES: THEORY AND HISTORICAL EVIDENCE ¨ S. ebnem Kalemli-Ozcan Carmen Reinhart University of Maryland, CEPR Harvard University and NBER and NBER Kenneth Rogoff Harvard University and NBER This issue of the Journal of the European Economic Association presents papers from the October 2013 conference on Sovereign Debt Crises organized by S. ebnem Kalemli-Ozcan,¨ Carmen Reinhart, and Kenneth Rogoff. This project arose from the need to provide rigorous research on the topic. The so-called “Great Contraction” in the world’s advanced economies is the most severe and synchronized global financial crisis since the Great Depression. It has forced all concerned parties to reassess the roles played by public and private debt, as well as the importance of international financial linkages. Nations in the European Union continue to struggle with a crisis over the debts of periphery countries, most notably Greece but also Ireland, Spain, Portugal, and Italy. The failure of most advanced countries to recover—or to regain pre- crisis levels of employment and growth in its aftermath—raises fears of experiencing the equivalent of Japan’s “lost decade”. In the wake of the crisis, it is clear that the macroeconomic models previously used by central banks and others have severe limitations. In particular, these models do not adequately incorporate financial frictions and are almost always estimated over relatively narrow data sets that do not span financial crises. The recent crisis also raises many other issues, including the links among government and private sector debt, the financial sector, and the political processes governing the resolution of fiscal and financial distress.
    [Show full text]