Vertical Agreements in 35 Jurisdictions Worldwide 2014 Contributing Editor: Stephen Kinsella OBE

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Vertical Agreements in 35 Jurisdictions Worldwide 2014 Contributing Editor: Stephen Kinsella OBE Vertical Agreements in 35 jurisdictions worldwide 2014 Contributing editor: Stephen Kinsella OBE Published by Getting the Deal Through in association with: Accura Advokatpartnerselskab Advokatfirmaet Steenstrup Stordrange DA Allende & Brea Antitrust Advisory Ashurst Advokatbyrå AB Asters Baker & McKenzie Bán, S Szabó & Partners Banning NV Caiado Guerreiro & Associados Cortázar Urdaneta & Cía – Abogados De Berti Jacchia Franchini Forlani Dentons Europe CS LLP Glade Michel Wirtz Golfinopoulos Law Office Herbert Smith Freehills LLP Homburger J Sagar Associates King & Wood Mallesons Korman & Oren Kramer Levin Legal and Economic Avantgarde SC Levy & Salomão Advogados Matheson Momo-o Matsuo & Namba Peli Filip SCA Pellegrini & Cía Sidley Austin LLP Soewito Suhardiman Eddymurthy Kardono (SSEK) Vivien & Associés Wolf Theiss Zaid Ibrahim & Co CONTENTS Vertical Agreements 2014 Increased Scrutiny of Most Favoured Nation European Union 79 Clauses in Vertical Agreements 3 Stephen Kinsella OBE, Stephen Spinks, Contributing editor: Noëlle Lenoir, Marco Plankensteiner and Patrick Harrison and Rosanna Connolly Stephen Kinsella OBE Elise Créquer Sidley Austin LLP Sidley Austin LLP Kramer Levin France 92 Argentina 6 Muriel Perrier Getting the Deal Through is delighted Julián Peña Vivien & Associés Allende & Brea to publish the eighth edition of Vertical Agreements, a volume in our series of Germany 100 annual reports that provide international Australia 13 Markus M Wirtz and Silke Möller analysis in key areas of law and policy Wayne Leach and Sharon Henrick Glade Michel Wirtz for corporate counsel, cross-border legal King & Wood Mallesons practitioners and business people. Greece 110 Austria 21 Christos Golfinopoulos Following the format adopted throughout Guenter Bauer and Robert Wagner Golfinopoulos Law Office the series, the same key questions are Wolf Theiss answered by leading practitioners in each of the 35 jurisdictions featured. New Hungary 119 Brazil 29 jurisdictions this year include Indonesia, Chrysta Bán Norway, Russia and Sweden. There is also Alexandre Ditzel Faraco, Ana Paula Bán, S Szabó & Partners a new chapter on most-favoured-nation Martinez and Mariana Tavares de Araujo Levy & Salomão Advogados clauses. India 127 Amit Kapur, Farhad Sorabjee and Every effort has been made to ensure Chile 37 Amitabh Kumar that matters of concern to readers are Julio Pellegrini and Pedro Rencoret J Sagar Associates covered. However, specific legal advice Pellegrini & Cía should always be sought from experienced Indonesia 136 local advisers. Getting the Deal Through China 45 Fahrul S Yusuf and Meta N Mustikaningrum publications are updated annually. Please Chen Yang and Lei Li Soewito Suhardiman Eddymurthy Kardono ensure you are referring to the latest print Sidley Austin LLP (SSEK) edition or to the online version at www.GettingTheDealThrough.com. Colombia 54 Ireland 143 Getting the Deal Through gratefully Javier Cortázar-Mora Helen Kelly acknowledges the efforts of all the Cortázar Urdaneta & Cía – Abogados Matheson contributors to this volume, who were chosen for their recognised expertise. We Czech Republic 61 Israel 151 would also like to extend special thanks Katerina Schenkova William B Korman and Nachum Oren to contributing editor Stephen Kinsella Baker & McKenzie Korman & Oren OBE of Sidley Austin LLP for his continued assistance with this volume. Denmark 70 Italy 162 Getting the Deal Through Christina Heiberg-Grevy and Fabio Ferraro and Andrew G Paton Malene Gry-Jensen De Berti Jacchia Franchini Forlani London Accura Advokatpartnerselskab March 2014 Publisher The information provided in this publication is Gideon Roberton Law general and may not apply in a specific situation. [email protected] Legal advice should always be sought before Business taking any legal action based on the information Subscriptions provided. This information is not intended to Rachel Nurse Research create, nor does receipt of it constitute, a lawyer– [email protected] client relationship. The publishers and authors Published by accept no responsibility for any acts or omissions Business development managers Law Business Research Ltd contained herein. Although the information George Ingledew 87 Lancaster Road provided is accurate as of March 2014, be [email protected] London W11 1QQ, UK advised that this is a developing area. Tel: +44 20 7908 1188 Alan Lee Fax: +44 20 7229 6910 Printed and distributed by [email protected] © Law Business Research Ltd 2014 Encompass Print Solutions No photocopying: copyright licences do not apply. Tel: 0844 2480 112 Dan White First published 2007 [email protected] Eighth edition 2014 ISSN 1753-9250 www.gettingthedealthrough.com 1 CONTENTS Japan 174 Romania 224 Switzerland 271 Nobuaki Mukai Carmen Peli and Manuela Lupeanu Franz Hoffet, Marcel Dietrich, Gerald Brei Momo-o, Matsuo & Namba Peli Filip SCA and Barbara Wälchli Homburger Malaysia 183 Russia 235 Sharon Tan Alexander Egorushkin and Igor Panshensky Ukraine 280 Zaid Ibrahim & Co Antitrust Advisory Igor Svechkar and Oleksandr Voznyuk Asters Mexico 191 Serbia 243 León Ricardo Elizondo Castro Guenter Bauer and Maja Stankovi´c United Kingdom 288 Legal and Economic Avantgarde SC Wolf Theiss Stephen Kinsella OBE, David Went, Patrick Harrison and Rosanna Connolly Sidley Austin LLP Netherlands 199 Slovakia 251 Minos van Joolingen and Martijn Jongmans Katarína Pecnová Banning NV Dentons Europe CS LLP United States 301 Joel Mitnick Sidley Austin LLP Norway 208 Spain 258 Thomas Sando and Aksel Joachim Hageler Luis Blanquez and Manuel Contreras Advokatfirmaet Steenstrup Stordrange DA Herbert Smith Freehills LLP Portugal 216 Sweden 265 Joana Gomes dos Santos Mats Johnsson and Elsa Arbrandt Caiado Guerreiro & Associados Ashurst Advokatbyrå AB 2 Getting the Deal Through – Vertical Agreements 2014 Sidley Austin LLP UNITED STATES United States Joel Mitnick Sidley Austin LLP Antitrust law Types of vertical restraint 1 What are the legal sources that set out the antitrust law applicable to 2 List and describe the types of vertical restraints that are subject vertical restraints? to antitrust law. Is the concept of vertical restraint defined in the A number of federal statutes bear directly on the legality of verti- antitrust law? cal restraints. Section 1 of the Sherman Act is the federal antitrust The varying forms of vertical restraints are not expressly defined by statute most often cited in vertical restraint cases. Section 1 prohibits statute. Rather, these concepts have evolved through judicial decision- ‘every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or making, which is commonly referred to as the ‘common law’ of conspiracy, in restraint of trade’ (15 USC, section 1 (2006)). Section antitrust. Numerous types of vertical restraints have been the subject 1 serves as a basis for challenges to such vertical restraints as resale of review under the applicable antitrust laws, the most common of price maintenance, exclusive dealing, tying, and certain customer or which are the following: territorial restraints on the resale of goods. • resale price maintenance – agreements between persons at dif- Unlike section 1, section 2 of the Sherman Act reaches single-firm ferent levels of the distribution structure on the price at which a conduct. Section 2 declares that ‘every person who shall monopolise customer will resell the goods or services supplied. Resale price or attempt to monopolise […] any part of the trade or commerce maintenance can take the form of setting a specific price; but among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed commonly it involves either setting a price floor below which guilty of a felony’ (15 USC, section 2 (2006)). In the distribution (minimum resale price maintenance) or a price ceiling above context, section 2 may apply where a firm has market power which (maximum resale price maintenance) sales cannot occur; significant enough to raise prices or limit market output unilaterally. • customer and territorial restraints – these involve a supplier or Section 3 of the Clayton Act makes it unlawful to sell goods on upstream manufacturer of a product prohibiting a distributor the condition that the purchaser refrain from buying a competitor’s from selling outside an assigned territory or particular category goods if the effect may be to substantially lessen competition (15 of customers; USC, section 14 (2006)). • channel of distribution restraints – these function similarly to Finally, section 5(a)(1) of the Federal Trade Commission Act customer or territorial restraints in that an upstream manufac- (FTC Act) has application to vertical restraints. This declares turer or supplier of a product prohibits a distributor from selling unlawful unfair methods of competition (15 USC, section 45(a)(1) outside an approved channel of distribution. Commonly, such (2006)). Section 5(a)(1) violations are solely within the jurisdiction restraints involve a luxury goods manufacturer prohibiting its of the FTC. As a general matter, the FTC has interpreted the FTC distributors from selling over the internet; Act consistently with the sections of the Sherman and Clayton Acts • exclusive dealing arrangements – these require a buyer to pur- applicable to vertical restraints. In December 2009, however, the chase products or services for a period of time exclusively from FTC filed a complaint against Intel Corp in which the FTC asserted one supplier. The arrangement may take the form of an agree-
Recommended publications
  • Vertical Restraints – an Economic Perspective
    Vertical restraints – an economic perspective Patrick Rey Revised draft report 13 October 2012 Table of contents A. Methodology 4 B. Report 5 I. Introduction 5 1. Vertical restraints 5 a. Payment schemes 6 b. Provisions specifying the parties’ rights 6 2. The Chilean Competition Law 7 II. The Economic Role of Vertical Restraints 8 1. Vertical coordination 9 a. Double marginalization 10 . The vertical price coordination problem 10 . Adequate vertical restraints can solve this coordination problem 10 . Impact on consumers and society 11 b. Retail services 12 . Vertical externalities 12 . Horizontal externalities 13 . Which restraints can enhance coordination? 14 . Policy discussion 15 c. Other coordination problems 16 . Product mix 16 . Upstream decisions 17 . Risk-sharing 17 . Hold-up 18 1 . Policy implications 18 2. Impact on competition in the short-term 19 a. Collusion 19 . Downstream collusion: Sham vertical agreements 19 . Upstream collusion: Facilitating practices 20 b. Competition-dampening 21 . Softening inter-brand competition through strategic delegation 21 . Key factors 23 . Policy implications 24 c. Commitment problems 24 . Restoring the exercise of market power 24 . Policy implications 26 d. Common agency and interlocking relationships 26 . Common agency 27 . Interlocking relationships 27 . Policy implications 29 3. Impact on competition in the long-term 30 a. Entry stimulation 30 b. Vertical foreclosure 31 . Raising rivals’ costs 31 . Exclusionary clauses as a rent-extraction device 32 . Buyers’ miscoordination 34 . Preserving market power 35 . Buyer power 37 . Pre-commitment effects 38 2 . Policy implications 38 III. Policy implications: the case of Resale Price Maintenance 39 1. Efficiency benefits 40 a. Eliminating double marginalization 40 b.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Agreements Understanding Competition Law
    Vertical agreements Understanding competition law Competition law 2004 COMPETITION LAW GUIDELINE Since 1 May 2004 not only the European Commission, but also the Office of Fair Trading (OFT) has the power to apply and enforce Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty in the United Kingdom. The OFT also has the power to apply and enforce the Competition Act 1998. In relation to the regulated sectors the same provisions are applied and enforced, concurrently with the OFT, by the regulators for communications matters, gas, electricity, water and sewerage, railway and air traffic services (under section 54 and schedule 10 of the Competition Act 1998) (the Regulators). Throughout the guidelines, references to the OFT should be taken to include the Regulators in relation to their respective industries, unless otherwise specified. The following are the Regulators: • the Office of Communications (OFCOM) • the Gas and Electricity Markets Authority (OFGEM) • the Northern Ireland Authority for Energy Regulation (OFREG NI) • the Director General of Water Services (OFWAT) • the Office of Rail Regulation (ORR), and • the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA). Section 52 of the Competition Act 1998 obliges the OFT to prepare and publish general advice and information about the application and enforcement by the OFT of Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty and the Chapter I and Chapter II prohibitions contained in the Competition Act 1998. This guideline is intended to explain these provisions to those who are likely to be affected by them and to indicate how the OFT expects them to operate. Further information on how the OFT has applied and enforced competition law in particular cases may be found in the OFT’s decisions, as available on its website from time to time.
    [Show full text]
  • Identifying Monopolists' Illegal Conduct Under the Sherman Act
    NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW VOLUME 75 OCTOBER 2000 NUMBER 4 ARTICLES IDENTIFYING MONOPOLISTS' ILLEGAL CONDUCT UNDER THE SHERMAN ACT THOMAS A. Pmnn'io, JR.' Upon surveying antitrust enforcement pursuant to Section 2 of the Sherman Act, Thomas Pirainoconcludes that the standardfor determining violations has become muddled and confusing. He proposes a new standard to assist courts in distin- guishing beneficial from harmfid conduc; one that focuses on the monopolist's substantive competitive purpose. Under that standard, conduct should be illegal under Section 2 if it makes no economic sense other than as a means of perpetuat- ing or extending monopoly power. Pirainoillustrates the benefits of this proposed standard by applying it to the Microsoft litigation. Introduction .................................................... 810 I. The Economic Effects of Monopolies ................... 813 A. Harmful Effects of Monopolies ..................... 814 B. Beneficial Effects of Monopolies ................... 816 C. The Persistence of Monopoly Power ................ 818 D. Monopoly Leveraging ............................... 824 E. A Judicial Standard That Accounts for Monopolies' Economic Effects ................................... 824 II. The Courts' Failure to Develop an Effective Section 2 Standard ................................................ 826 A. Sources of the Courts' Difficulty .................... 826 B. The History of Section 2 Enforcement .............. 828 C. The Principal Wave III Cases ....................... 833 1. Restrictions on Access to Essential Products ... 833 * Vice President, General Counsel, and Secretary, Parker-Hannifin Corporation, Cleveland, Ohio. J.D., 1974, Cornell University. The opinions expressed in this Article are personal to the author and do not reflect the opinions of Parker-Hannifin Corporation. 809 Imaged with the Permission of N.Y.U. Law Review NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 75:809 2. Tying and Exclusive Dealing Arrangements ...
    [Show full text]
  • A Comprehensive Economic and Legal Analysis of Tying Arrangements
    A Comprehensive Economic and Legal Analysis of Tying Arrangements Guy Sagi* I. INTRODUCTION The law of tying arrangements as it stands does not correspond with modern economic analysis. Therefore, and because tying arrangements are so widely common, the law is expected to change and extensive aca- demic writing is currently attempting to guide its way. In tying arrangements, monopolistic firms coerce consumers to buy additional products or services beyond what they intended to purchase.1 This pressure can be applied because a consumer in a monopolistic mar- ket does not have the alternative to buy the product or service from a competing firm. In the absence of such choice, the monopolistic firm can allegedly force the additional purchase on the consumer at non-beneficial terms. The “tying product” is the one the consumer wants to buy, and the product the firm attaches to the tying product is termed the “tied prod- 2 uct.” * Lecturer, Netanya Academic College; Adjunct Lecturer, The Hebrew University School of Law; LL.B., The Hebrew University School of Law; LL.M. and J.S.D. Columbia University School of Law. 1. In a competitive market, consumers can choose to buy from firms that do not tie products, as opposed to ones that do. The tying firm, in such a case, would then lose out. At the same time, it is possible that in a competitive market, some products would still be offered together because it would be beneficial to both producers and consumers. 2. It can sometimes be difficult to differentiate between the tying of two separate products and the sale of two components forming a single whole product.
    [Show full text]
  • LAW COMPETITION LAW Vertical Agreements Under Competition Act
    LAW COMPETITION LAW Vertical agreements under Competition Act 2002 Q1: E-TEXT Module ID 14: Vertical Agreements under Competition Act, 2002 Module Overview: In this module, provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 that deal with vertical agreements have been discussed at length. Section 3(4) of the act describes agreement amongst enterprises or persons at different stages of the production-supply chain in different markets with regard to goods or services to be anti-competitive if such agreement causes or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition. The inclusive nature of the definition has been discussed along with the types of such agreements. Since such agreements are not bad per se, rule of reason has been applied by the Commission. Various market forces that are needed to find about anti-competitiveness of such agreements, as provided under Sec.19 (3) have been talked about briefly. Further, if such arrangement amongst the enterprises causes adverse effect on competition, these are prohibited under Section 3 of the Act. Also, impacts of such agreements on competition in India have been discussed. Subject Name: Law Paper Name: Competition Law Module ID: 14 Pre-requisites: For understanding the module, basic knowledge of anti-competitive agreements and the related provisions in the Competition Act, 2002 is required. Objectives: • The main objective of the module is to discuss about provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 pertaining to vertical agreements ; • To appraise the students of various types of vertical
    [Show full text]
  • A Proposal to Enhance Antitrust Protection Against Labor Market Monopsony Roosevelt Institute Working Paper
    A Proposal to Enhance Antitrust Protection Against Labor Market Monopsony Roosevelt Institute Working Paper Ioana Marinescu, University of Pennsylvania Eric A. Posner, University of Chicago1 December 21, 2018 1 We thank Daniel Small, Marshall Steinbaum, David Steinberg, and Nancy Walker and her staff, for helpful comments. 1 The United States has a labor monopsony problem. A labor monopsony exists when lack of competition in the labor market enables employers to suppress the wages of their workers. Labor monopsony harms the economy: the low wages force workers out of the workforce, suppressing economic growth. Labor monopsony harms workers, whose wages and employment opportunities are reduced. Because monopsonists can artificially restrict labor mobility, monopsony can block entry into markets, and harm companies who need to hire workers. The labor monopsony problem urgently calls for a solution. Legal tools are already in place to help combat monopsony. The antitrust laws prohibit employers from colluding to suppress wages, and from deliberately creating monopsonies through mergers and other anticompetitive actions.2 In recent years, the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice Department have awoken from their Rip Van Winkle labor- monopsony slumber, and brought antitrust cases against employers and issued guidance and warnings.3 But the antitrust laws have rarely been used by private litigants because of certain practical and doctrinal weaknesses. And when they have been used—whether by private litigants or by the government—they have been used against only the most obvious forms of anticompetitive conduct, like no-poaching agreements. There has been virtually no enforcement against abuses of monopsony power more generally.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Agreements and Dominant Firms 2019 3Rd Edition a Practical Cross-Border Insight Into Vertical Agreements and Dominant Firms
    ICLG The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Vertical Agreements and Dominant Firms 2019 3rd Edition A practical cross-border insight into vertical agreements and dominant firms Published by Global Legal Group, with contributions from: ALRUD Law Firm HLG Avocats AZB & Partners Johnson Winter & Slattery Baker Botts LLP Kennedy Van der Laan Barun Law LLC Lee & Lee Callol, Coca & Asociados Nagashima Ohno & Tsunematsu DDPV Studio Legale Noerr LLP DeHeng Law Offices Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP Dickson Minto Pinheiro Neto Advogados ELIG Gürkaynak Attorneys-at-Law Stavropoulos & Partners Law Office Gorrissen Federspiel SyCip Salazar Hernandez & Gatmaitan The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Vertical Agreements and Dominant Firms 2019 Country Question and Answer Chapters: 1 Australia Johnson Winter & Slattery: Sar Katdare & Jaime Campbell 1 2 Brazil Pinheiro Neto Advogados: Leonardo Rocha e Silva & Daniel Costa Rebello 8 Contributing Editors Charles F. (Rick) Rule & Andrew J. Forman Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, 3 China DeHeng Law Offices: Ding Liang 15 Wharton & Garrison LLP Sales Director Florjan Osmani 4 Denmark Gorrissen Federspiel: Martin André Dittmer & Kristian Helge Andersen 26 Account Director Oliver Smith 5 European Union Baker Botts LLP: Matthew Levitt & Daniel Vasbeck 33 Sales Support Manager Toni Hayward Editor 6 France HLG Avocats: Helen Coulibaly-Le Gac & Pierre Laforet 40 Nicholas Catlin Senior Editors Caroline Collingwood 7 Germany Noerr LLP: Peter Stauber & Robert Pahlen 47 Rachel Williams CEO Dror Levy 8 Greece Stavropoulos & Partners Law Office: Evanthia Tsiri & Efthymia Armata 59 Group Consulting Editor Alan Falach 9 India AZB & Partners: Hemangini Dadwal & Aakarsh Narula 65 Publisher Rory Smith Published by 10 Italy DDPV Studio Legale: Luciano Vasques 76 Global Legal Group Ltd.
    [Show full text]
  • LAW COMPETITION LAW Horizontal Agreements and Their Types
    LAW COMPETITION LAW Horizontal agreements and their types Q1: E-TEXT Module ID: 10 Horizontal Agreements and their types Module Overview: This module is an introductory module on horizontal agreements covered under the competition law. It will deal with the basics of horizontal agreements, types of such agreements, reasons for collusion by businesses and regulation of such agreements by the competition authority. It will also cover horizontal agreements like market allocation, controlling production and bid rigging. The module will also discuss cartelisation and the ways to detect and prevent cartelisation. Subject Name: Law Paper Name: Competition Law Module ID: 10 Pre-requisites: Competition law is an economic law and thus an understanding of various market structures like monopoly and oligopoly will help readers better understand the reasons for businesses colluding to gain market power. Basic knowledge about microeconomics will also help in appreciating the adverse effects the horizontal anticompetitive agreements can have on economy and consumers and the reasons for regulating such conduct. Objectives: After reading this module, the readers will be able to appreciate as to why the anticompetitive effects of the horizontal agreements and practices need to be regulated by the competition law. Further, the readers will learn regarding the different types of horizontal agreements. A reader will realise as to why cartels which are a form of horizontal agreements are given stern treatment under the competition laws worldwide. Further, the reader will also understand as to why there is more international convergence and consensus in dealing with hard-core cartels which have anticompetitive effects on consumers across the borders.
    [Show full text]
  • The Use of Tying Requirements in Patent Licensing
    Marquette University Law School Marquette Law Scholarly Commons Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 1-1-1981 The seU of Tying Requirements in Patent Licensing Ramon A. Klitzke Marquette University Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.marquette.edu/facpub Part of the Law Commons Publication Information Ramon A. Klitzke, The sU e of Tying Requirements in Patent Licensing, 9 APLA Q.J. 333 (1981) Copyright, 1982, Ramon A. Klitzke Repository Citation Klitzke, Ramon A., "The sU e of Tying Requirements in Patent Licensing" (1981). Faculty Publications. Paper 539. http://scholarship.law.marquette.edu/facpub/539 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Marquette Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Marquette Law Scholarly Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. TYING THE USE OF TYING REQUIREMENTS IN PATENT LICENSING BY RAMON A. KLITZKE* Tying is the sale or license of an item (the tying item) upon the condition that another item (the tied item) be purchased. When the tying item pos- sesses sufficient economic power, "to appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product,"I the antitrust laws are violated. The requisite power is presumed when the tying product is patented or copy- righted.2 To tie a product or service to a patent therefore violates the anti- trust laws. The major patent tying cases will be examined in this article. The features of tying arrangements that are either violations of the antitrust statutes or pat- ent misuse will be sketched.
    [Show full text]
  • A Structured Outline for the Analysis of Horizontal Agreements
    A STRUCTURED OUTLINE FOR THE ANALYSIS OF HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS by Thomas B. Leary* The antitrust principles applied to “horizontal” arrangements are difficult to summarize. The principles have evolved over an extended period of time and have been shaped by decisions that are often hard to reconcile. I do not claim that the structure outlined below is the only way to read cases or frame issues, but it is one that I believe is consistent with the most recent precedent and learning. I. Introduction An agreement between actual or potential competitors to restrain their rivalry in some respect is commonly called a “horizontal restraint.” This kind of agreement should be distinguished from so-called “vertical” restraints that govern the interface between supplier and customers (who may also be competitors in another capacity). The distinction is fundamental because horizontal and vertical restraints are analyzed in different ways.1 The most significant difference is that horizontal restraints are more likely to be deemed illegal per se and vertical restraints are more likely to be subject to the “rule of reason.” * Commissioner, Federal Trade Commission. This revision of a paper first presented a year ago has been prepared for distribution at The Conference Board 2004 Antitrust Conference (Mar. 3-4, 2004). I have benefitted from discussions with FTC Chairman Timothy Muris, General Counsel William Kovacic, and attorney advisors Thomas Klotz, Lisa Kopchik and Holly Vedova in the preparation of this outline, but it does not necessarily reflect their views or the views of anyone else in the Commission. 1 See, e.g., discussion in ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 79-82 (5th ed.
    [Show full text]
  • Tying and Consumer Harm Daniel A
    University of Michigan Law School University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository Articles Faculty Scholarship 2012 Tying and Consumer Harm Daniel A. Crane University of Michigan Law School, [email protected] Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/articles/1374 Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/articles Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Communications Law Commons, and the Consumer Protection Law Commons Recommended Citation Crane, Daniel A. "Tying and Consumer Harm." Competition Pol'y. Int'l. 8, no. 2 (2012). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Articles by an authorized administrator of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Volume 8 | Number 2 | Autumn 2012 Tying and Consumer Harm Daniel Crane University of Michigan Law School Tying and Consumer Harm 27 TYING AND CONSUMER HARM Daniel Crane* ABSTRACT: Brantley raises important issues of law, economics, and policy about tying arrangements. Under current legal principles, Brantley was on solid ground in distinguishing between anticompetitive ties and those that might harm consumer interests without impairing competition. As a mat- ter of economics, the court was also right to reject the claim that the cable programmers forced consumers to pay for programs the customers didn’t want. The hardest question is a policy one - whether antitrust law should ever condemn the exploitation of market power in ways that extract surplus from consumers but do not create or enlarge market power.
    [Show full text]
  • Tying By: Kate Wallace
    The American Bar Association Young Lawyers Division The 101 Practice Series: Breaking Down the Basics The Wonderful World of Tying By: Kate Wallace A tying arrangement is an agreement between a seller and a buyer under which the seller agrees to sell a product or service (the tying product) to the buyer only on the condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product from the seller or the buyer agrees not to purchase the tied product from any other seller. Tying arrangements can be used to tie together not only different products but also services, leases, franchises, licenses to intellectual property, or combinations of any of those things. Tying arrangements may be challenged under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, which prohibits “contracts in restraint of trade,” Section 3 of the Clayton Act, which prohibits exclusivity arrangements that may “substantially lessen competition,” and Section 5 of the FTC Act, which prohibits “[u]nfair methods of competition.” Tying may also constitute conduct supporting a monopolization claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. For many years tying arrangements were thought worthy of per se condemnation without examination of any actual competitive effects. But strong disapproval of tying claims has waned over the past few decades, as courts have recognized that tying arrangements may have procompetitive benefits. Tying currently is generally deemed per se unlawful only if: • Separate Products: Two separate products or services are involved; • Coercion: The sale or agreement to sell one product or service is conditioned on the buyer’s agreement to purchase another product or service; • Market Power: The seller has sufficient power in the market for the tying product to enable it to restrain competition in the market for the tied product; and • Not Insubstantial Amount of Commerce Affected: The tying arrangement affects a “not insubstantial” amount of commerce.1 In addition, some courts have stated that proof of an anticompetitive effect in the market for the tied product is required for per se liability.
    [Show full text]