௠ The Academy of Management Perspectives 2014, Vol. 28, No. 4, 430–446. http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amp.2013.0039 ARTICLES

ESCALATION OF COMMITMENT: WHEN TO STAY THE COURSE?

HELGA DRUMMOND University of Liverpool

When an important venture seems to unravel, decision makers may face a dilemma. Do they persist and risk becoming caught up in a spiral of escalating commitment, or “apply the brakes” when they may be within an ace of success? Escalation of commitment is thought to be a ubiquitous and costly mistake. Yet sometimes organizations should “press on the accelerator” and stay the course despite adversity. This paper explores what might drive organizations to erroneously abandon a potentially successful venture.

Through adversity to the stars. And despite a decade of losses totaling roughly Motto of the British Royal Air Force $8.5 billion, Sony is reluctant to exit its electronics In 1961 a remarkable event occurred in the business (Tabuchi, 2014). What drives organiza- Libyan desert. For seven fruitless years an entre- tions to throw good money after bad? preneur named Bunker Nelson Hunt and British The question has intrigued scholars of organiza- Petroleum (BP) had drilled for oil. Finally, oper- tion behavior, as evidenced by the burgeoning cor- atives were told to stop and come home. This pus of research (for reviews see Brockner, 1992; is not what they did, however. Giving it just one Drummond & Hodgson, 2011; Sleesman, Conlon, more chance, the rig superintendent drilled an- McNamara, & Miles, 2012; Staw, 1997; Staw & other 3 meters into the sand before removing the Ross, 1987a). Yet few studies mention the opposite bit and, in doing so, uncovered Hunt’s ace. That form of error. What might drive organizations to extra 3 meters made all the difference in the abandon an economically viable project, as BP so discovery of what was to become one of the nearly did? world’s largest oil fields (Fay, 1982). This question is important because giving up too Almost any venture involving uncertainty can soon can mean losing stellar rewards. Consider, for fail. When an important venture appears to falter example, Pepsi Raw, a new drink made of natural managers may face a dilemma: Do they quit or ingredients that was abandoned after a two-year continue? Instead of culling poor projects, manag- trial in the United Kingdom. Having invested so ers may reinvest in them well beyond an econom- much, and come so far, should Pepsi have tested ically defensible point, a phenomenon known as the product in at least one other country before escalation of commitment (e.g., Staw, 1976). Exam- giving up? Microsoft sold tablet computers long ples abound. The U.S. Air Force wasted six years before the Apple iPad appeared. Should Microsoft and $1 billion on a new combat support system that have persisted with its invention? Was it wise of didn’t work (Stross, 2012). It took six years and Hewlett-Packard to withdraw its first tablet com- losses of at least £850 million to persuade Tesco puter just days after launching the product? Appar- that its plan to storm the United States via its ently only one third of divested foreign operations “Fresh and Easy” brand had failed (Butler, 2012). of U.S. firms were actually unprofitable (Berry, 2013). Were some of those divestments unwise? The author gratefully acknowledges help from Profes- We will probably never know if these ventures sors Elena Antonacopoulou, Andy Lyons, and Tony Pat- would have succeeded if pursued. Abandonment terson and two anonymous referees. The paper is dedi- can be described as erroneous only if the decision cated to Hilary Gorman. maker’s information suggests there is a reasonable

430 Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright holder’s express written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only. 2014 Drummond 431

TABLE 1 Persistence vs. Abandonment

chance that persistence will yield success. (Discov- mitment (Staw, 1997, p. 209). Managers may mis- ering Hunt’s ace was sheer luck because experience allocate resources in adversity. But escalation is not suggested that drilling was futile.)1 Yet we know the only mistake they can make (Heath, 1995, that decision makers may quit investing when ex- makes a similar point). perience tells them nothing (e.g., Brockner, Rubin, The gaps in the literature outlined here lead to & Lang, 1981; Heath, 1995). Researchers may even three focal questions: have missed instances of erroneous abandonment because they were not looking for it (Heath, 1995). 1. What might produce a breakdown of decision These contraindicators suggest that it may be im- rationality in the opposite direction to escala- portant to educate managers to avoid escalation as tion (i.e., abandonment)? well as the opposite form of error, which is giving up 2. Under what conditions are organizations likely too soon (Heath, 1995). For instance, which is worse, to be more prone to erroneous abandonment giving up too late or too soon? This question has been than to erroneous escalation? ignored by most researchers, perhaps because the fo- 3. How can organizations get decisions more right cus on avoiding escalation detracts from situations than wrong? where organizations should press on the accelerator The exploration of these questions unfolds as despite adversity. Consequently, there has been little follows. First I sketch what are thought to be the synthesis of the conceptual tools or that main escalation drivers (i.e., the forces for persis- might help an organization stay the course when it is tence) to create a springboard to discuss why per- wise to do so. This largely conceptual and theoretical sistence may be justified despite adversity. I then paper begins to address this gap. explore what counterforces may enter the equation Why does the gap exist? Reviewers agree that and discuss under what conditions organizations rather than adding to the long list of potential driv- are most likely to be vulnerable to erroneous aban- ers, we need a more nuanced understanding of donment. The paper ends with issues for research escalation (see especially Sleesman and colleagues, and practice. 2012; Staw, 1997). Exploring the opposite promises to move the conversation in that direction (Camerer & Weber, 1999, p. 80, discusses this point). More specifically, escalation theorists tend to assume WHAT DRIVES ESCALATION? FORCES FOR that behavior is driven by a small set of one-direc- PERSISTENCE tional forces. Yet beleaguered managers may con- In theory, a venture fails when experience con- front multiple and conflicting forces. We know a lot sistently suggests that important expectations about the pressures to persist. We know a lot less will not be met (e.g., Bowen, 1987; Camerer & about what counterforces may enter the equation Weber, 1999). The left side of Table 1 summarizes and how they may affect the ebb and flow of com- what are thought to be the main escalation driv- ers (Sleesman et al., 2012; Staw, 1997; Staw & 1 I am grateful to an anonymous referee for this Ross, 1987a): overconfidence, sunk costs, per- definition. ceived need for self-justification, denial, social 432 The Academy of Management Perspectives November costs of admitting failure, completion effects, and expected to reevaluate the project and persist only exit barriers/organizational entrenchment. if it still makes economic sense. Escalation theo- rists believe, however, that managers may ignore such advice because they have too much invested Overconfidence to quit (Teger, 1980). In other words, although these The seeds of project failure are often sown by sunk costs are irrelevant because they cannot influ- overconfident planners (e.g., Flyvbjerg, Garbuio, & ence outcomes, managers may be reluctant to forgo Lovallo, 2009; Staw & Ross, 1987a, 1987b). More them (Arkes & Blumer, 1985; Garland, 1990). specifically, psychologists believe that most people overestimate their abilities (e.g., Taylor, 1980). For example, Tesco expected to succeed even though Perceived Need for Self-Justification several British retailers had failed in the United States (Butler, 2012). Likewise, Tata expected the Part of the cost of quitting may be psychologi- Nano to be a huge success, but few Indian consum- cal. To be more precise, self-justification theory ers wanted to own the world’s cheapest car. suggests that managers who invest scarce re- Organizations use sophisticated planning and sources will be driven to persist to prove to them- forecasting tools to nullify human foibles. But selves and significant others that their decision these tools can heighten overconfidence because was correct (e.g., Brockner, 1992; Drummond, they are typically inward looking, focused on the 1994; Staw, 1976). organization’s capabilities and aspirations and blind to competition and results of similar proj- Denial ects elsewhere (Lovallo & Kahneman, 2003). Al- though senior managers can revise overly optimis- Self-justification may be accompanied by denial tic prognostications, those revisions are rarely and other ego-defensive behaviors. For instance, drastic enough because the initial cost/benefits es- experience in the real world is usually equivocal, timates tend to act as powerful anchors (e.g., capable of both positive and negative interpretation Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993; Kahneman, Lovallo, & (e.g., Bowen, 1987; Camerer & Weber, 1999). Man- Sibony, 2011). agers in denial tend to pay more attention to posi- Delusion may be compounded by deception. Po- tive experience and information while downplay- litically adroit planners may conceal the true costs ing or even ignoring negative experience (Nisbett & of a project and exaggerate the benefits knowing Ross, 1980; Staw & Ross, 1978; Zhang & Baumeis- that by the time the truth emerges, they will have ter, 2006). moved on. Contractors eager to win work may sub- Since such confirmation traps tend to operate mit artificially low bids, knowing that overruns unconsciously, managers may genuinely believe will be tolerated (Flyvbjerg et al., 2009; Lovallo, that a success is close when objective analysis Viguerie, Uhlaner, & Horn, 2007). For instance, clearly suggests otherwise (Conlon & Parks, 1987). Taurus was a £50 million (1993 figures) IT infra- For instance, an experiment by Boulding, Morgan, structure project intended to replace the London and Staelin (1997) found that 80% of participants Stock Exchange’s antiquated paper-driven system persisted with a project even though experience for securities trading. Stakeholders insisted on a strongly suggested that persistence would end in maximum timescale of 18 months. Project manag- failure. Rather than quit, participants interpreted ers believed this was highly optimistic—one man- experience to justify persistence. Similarly, when ager noted that graphs plotting planned deliver- Taurus was running over 18 months late, a member ables against actuals “were showing delivery at of the project-monitoring group said, “I think [the infinity” (Drummond, 1996, p. 98)—but no one project team] . . . couldn’t believe that it wouldn’t protested publicly, and the 18-month timescale work. They believed they knew how to make it proved hopelessly unrealistic. work but it would just take longer and would cost a bit more” (Drummond, 1996, p. 141). Sunk Costs Social Costs of Admitting Failure Eventually, chickens return to roost. Costs over- run, deadlines slip, and promised benefits may Admitting failure privately is hard; admitting it start to look doubtful. In such cases, managers are publicly is harder still. Self-presentation theory 2014 Drummond 433 suggests that people strategically manage impres- To summarize these seven forces for persistence, sions, striving to appear competent and in control escalation theorists believe that managers may see (Goffman, 1959). The theory implies that managers their predicament as follows. Abandonment means may persist to maintain face (Staw & Ross, 1987b; incurring a sure loss—loss of and cred- Teger, 1980). For instance, firms are often slow to ibility, increased exiting costs, and major upheaval. deinternationalize operations because the wider Persistence offers a small chance of avoiding that business community sees divestment as failure loss, but risks seriously compounding it. Prospect (e.g., Benito & Welch, 1997; Decker & Mellewigt, theory predicts that when choices are negatively 2007). This may be one reason why Tesco did not expressed (framed) in this way, managers tend to abandon its U.S. venture sooner. become risk seeking. That is, a small chance of success and risk of bigger losses is preferable to accepting a sure loss (e.g., Kahneman & Tversky, Completion Effects 1979, 1982; Whyte, 1986). Even if failure is acknowledged, quitting can be prohibitively expensive—particularly if little can WHEN TO STAY THE COURSE? be salvaged from the project (Porter, 1976; Staw & If decision makers gave up whenever important Ross, 1987a). Contractors may levy penalties; there objectives were not met, projects such as the Syd- may be redundancy payments, costs of ripping out ney Opera House, the refurbishment of London’s partially completed work, and obligations on Savoy Hotel, and Amsterdam’s new subway system leases. For example, planning for the London would never have been finished. Indeed, cost over- (2012) Olympics began in 2005. When the world runs and benefit shortfalls of 50% happen regularly financial crisis broke in 2008, it was too late to turn in major projects. Even overruns of 100% are not back as hundreds of contracts had already been let. unusual (e.g., Flyvbjerg et al., 2009; Keil & Mähring, Similarly, Tesco expects to pay £250 million to 2010). But not all runaways should be culled. In a £500 million on top of existing losses to exit the provocative paper titled “Dollars, Sense, and Sunk U.S. market (Felsted, 2013). Costs,” Gregory Northcraft and Gerrit Wolf (1984) Ultimately completion rather than success may argued that persistence may be economically wise become all important (Conlon & Garland, 1993). despite severe cost overruns and/or benefit short- For instance, the technical team realized that Tau- falls. This determination, said the authors, should rus would never work as envisaged. Latterly, all be based on three factors: (1) the size of the likely they cared about was finishing the task: “Let’s get cost overrun, (2) the likely benefit shortfall, and (3) the bloody thing done and behind us,” said one the timing of expected returns, known as the “re- manager (Drummond, 1996, p. 140). gion of rationality” (p. 233). The calculation is be- yond the scope of this paper, but the principle is simple: Even though a project will never live up to Exit Barriers/Organizational Entrenchment planners’ extravagant claims, persistence may still Over time, formidable exit barriers may be erected. make economic sense when future costs and the Vested interests may press for completion. For in- full range of future benefits are considered. In this stance, politically adroit executives may be econom- view, what matters is net gain. ical with the truth. If so, decision makers may end up In other words, projects should be seen not as a focusing primarily on the positive trends and dis- series of that began in the past, but as a counting worst-case scenarios, thereby boosting over- series of investments beginning now. For example, optimism (Bragger, Bragger, Hantula, & Kirnan, 1998; consider a filmmaking project. Say the projected cost Moon & Conlon, 2002). Organizational forces can also was $150 million. So far, actual costs are $200 mil- perpetuate economically poor projects. An elaborate lion, and the film will cost another $85 million to administrative infrastructure may have been created finish. Clearly, expectations have not been met. By to support the project. For example, full deinterna- contrast, expected box office returns are $200 million. tionalization typically involves major upheaval (e.g., Assuming that a half-finished film is worthless, the Benito & Welch, 1997). All in all, “sometimes it’s $200 million expected revenues far outstrip the $85 easier not to rock the boat,” concluded Straw and million cost of completion. Persistence makes eco- Ross in an article looking at organizational entrench- nomic sense even though it means spending $285 ment (1987b, p. 71). million to earn $200 million (Camerer & Weber, 434 The Academy of Management Perspectives November

1999). This view of persistence is summed up in the tive is partial because both persistence and aban- article by Northcraft and Wolf (1984, p. 233): donment entail a sure loss. That is, if a project requires more investment, then “[t]he forgone op- The more a manager has invested in a project early on, and the larger and later the payoffs, the wiser it portunity to invest those resources elsewhere be- is to stay in a project....Itshould not be surprising comes a certain and wasteful loss,” (Northcraft & that in many cases managers persist in a course of Neale, 1986, p. 350; italics in original). For exam- action even in the face of negative feedback. What ple, opponents of the U.K.’s proposed superfast rail may need explanation is why a manager may not project (HS2) have argued that the £80 billion in- persist when his or her project is well within the vestment could generate £320 billion of economic region of rationality. benefits if the money were spent on upgrading roads and existing railways (e.g., Stacey, 2013). FORCES FOR ABANDONMENT Research has consistently shown that awareness of opportunity costs curbs escalation (Harvey & Why might a manager abandon a project that Victoravich, 2009; McCain, 1986; Northcraft & is well within the region of rationality? Theory Neale, 1986)—sometimes even regardless of sunk limits what we see and how we see (e.g., Bachar- costs or completion (Keil, Truex, & Mixon, 1995). ach, 1989; Whetten, 1989). Escalation theorists For example, Northcraft and Neale (1986) found stress quitting costs, but persistence is not without that when opportunity costs were made plain, de- cost either. As mentioned earlier, managers may cision makers were more confident about selling a face conflicting pressures, namely the cost of quit- partially completed project than they were when ting versus the cost of persistence (Northcraft & opportunity costs were largely implicit. Early on Neale, 1986). The right side of Figure 1 summarizes opportunity costs may be obscured (Keil & Robey, the main counterforces for persistence adduced 1999). As experience becomes more consistently from extant theorizing and research: aversion to negative, however, managers may worry about the loss, opportunity costs, perceived risk of persis- possibility of being held responsible for an even tence, intolerance of failure, publicly stated limits, bigger loss—not just sunk costs and additional ex- reluctance to renew budgets, and shifting tides of iting costs, but the forgone opportunity cost as well organization. (Northcraft & Neale, 1986).

Aversion to Loss “That Decision Makes Itself”: Perceived Risk of Persistence Although managers may be overconfident, psy- chologists believe they are also deeply loss-averse More consistent negative experience plus grow- (e.g., Kahneman, 2011; Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993; ing awareness of opportunity costs is likely to high- March & Shapira, 1987). In this view, managers take light project risk. Research has consistently shown risks but only because they believe they will probably that perceived risk discourages persistence (e.g., never materialize (e.g., Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993). Drummond, 1996; Schaubroeck & Davis, 1994; But if those risks materialize, managers may start to Wong, 2005). For example, when it emerged that worry about the cost of persistence and the possibility Taurus would need another three years plus an of financial disaster (Drummond, 1995, 1996; Staw & additional £90 million to be completed a stake- Ross, 1987a; Wong, Yik, & Kwong, 2006). Moreover, a holder said, “Well, maybe that’s four years and considerable battery of research suggests that loss £120 million. There isn’t that amount of value in aversion can make people too cautious, preferring to the project....That decision makes itself” (Drum- avoid losses than realize gains (reviewed in Kahne- mond, 1996, p. 159). man, 2011). What factors might amplify the loss The risks of continuing with Taurus were huge. prospect? Yet managers may be reluctant to accept responsi- bility even if the probability of failure is small (Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993). Moreover, contrary to What Might Have Been: Opportunity Costs what escalation theorists believe, perceived risk Opportunity costs are one possibility. Recall, es- may override responsibility effects (e.g., Drum- calation theorists believe that persistence may be mond, 1995; Schaubroeck & Davis, 1994; Staw & ultimately driven by managers’ reluctance to incur Fox, 1977). For instance, Schaubroeck and Davis a sure loss (e.g., Whyte, 1986). Again, this perspec- found that when allocating resources for the future, 2014 Drummond 435 decision makers preferred the less risky of two proj- tiny than projects described positively (“glass ects regardless of what they chose initially. More- half-full”), even though the two situations are over, if a potential loss looms large, decision mak- mathematically equivalent. Such negative framing ers may not reinvest, even though their data say can also lower decision makers’ confidence in a they should take the risk (Schaubroeck & Davis, project (Kuvaas & Selart, 2004) and reinforce 1994). More recently, Wong and colleagues (2006) doubts about the wisdom of persisting (Bragger et found that participants tended to abandon situa- al., 1998). For example, firms experiencing prob- tions causing negative emotions. Indeed, said the lems in one country may become more pessimistic authors, escalation predicaments can stir such un- about all international operations and scale down pleasant anticipatory emotions that managers feel activities accordingly (Liesch, Welch, & Buckley, driven to escape regardless. Similarly, regret theory 2011). In short, doubt can be corrosive. predicts that people will avoid choices they may subsequently rue. Intolerance of Failure Those fears may be very real, as the conse- quences of both persistence and abandonment are How do managers resolve their doubts? De-esca- uncertain. In experiments, participants are usually lation research suggests that far from lapsing into provided with reliable information about future denial, managers soon recognize that expectations costs and benefits. In reality, those estimates can be are not being met (e.g., Bragger et al., 1998; Drum- fraught with error. For example, when Tullow Oil mond, 1995; Monteagre & Keil, 2000). Moreover, far abandoned North Sea explorations to pursue richer from being obsessed with justifying past decisions, possibilities in Uganda and Ghana, shares rose managers may be more interested in being seen as 827%. But some new wells have since proved acting rationally in the future to reassert their dry—wiping a third off Tullow’s share price (Ka- competence (Staw & Ross, 1978, and Wortman & vanagh, 2013). So persistence, scaling back, or out- Brehm, 1975, discuss psychological reactance) right abandonment may reflect what decision mak- through intensified control. For example, managers ers believe they are least likely to regret (Ku, 2008; are likely to place more emphasis on targets and Wong & Kwong, 2007). Regret theory implies that if monitoring of results and express intolerance of a project seems risky, and managers fear ruing any failure (e.g., Drummond, 1995, 1996; Keil & Robey, decision to reinvest, they are more likely to desist 1999). While such hypervigilance can curb unwar- than persist—particularly if seemingly attractive al- ranted persistence (e.g., Ross & Staw, 1991; Simon- ternative investment opportunities beckon. son & Staw, 1992), it makes erroneous abandon- Managers may sometimes see more risk than is ment more likely. normatively appropriate (e.g., Sitkin & Pablo, 1992; Sitkin & Weingart, 1995). That is, although manag- “Look Good to Quit”: Publicly Stated Limits ers analyze risk cognitively, they also react to it emotionally. Indeed, according to a study by Loe- There are two reasons why. First, these measures wenstein, Weber, Hsee, and Welch (2001, p. 280), are also substitution heuristics that deliberately ig- “People can experience fear reactions without even nore a lot of information. Just as triage enables knowing what they are afraid of.” To be more pre- prompt identification of casualties urgently need- cise, emotional reactions to risk are basically sub- ing medical attention (Gigerenzer, 2008; Gigerenzer stitution heuristics in which “the answer to an easy & Gaissmaier, 2011) but risks a live casualty being question (How do I feel about it?) serves as an left literally for dead, targets, limit setting, and so answer to a much harder question (What do I think forth stand as surrogates for the state of the project about it?)” (Kahneman, 2011, p. 139). as a whole. “Managers may mistake the map for the Besides, even when managers analyze risk cog- territory” (Taleb, 2008, p. xxv) and wrongly declare nitively, they may be prone to error. This is because failure—or use the map as an excuse to declare projects that are below expectations are usually bad failure. news. The human brain processes bad news more Second, limit setting can create social pressures thoroughly than good news (e.g., Kahneman, 2011). for consistency, resulting in “lock-in.” For in- Negatives, therefore, tend to weigh much more stance, Brockner and colleagues (1981) found that heavily than positives. For instance, Dunegan individuals who set limits in public (as distinct (1993) found that projects described negatively from those who set limits in private) tended to stop (“glass half-empty”) received more intense scru- investing when those limits were reached, even 436 The Academy of Management Perspectives November when their economic data said “persist.” After- Shifting Tides of Organization ward, participants in the study said they thought it Recall that escalation theorists believe that eco- would “look good” to quit. In other words, aban- nomically poor projects are frequently perpetuated donment can also provide a potentially attractive by organizational forces, including entrenched opportunity for managers to strategically manage management, organizational politics, and inertia impressions by appearing resolute and decisive. (e.g., Drummond, 1994; Staw & Ross, 1987). Again, this perspective is partial as it overlooks the shift- ing tides of organizations (Staw, 1997) and manag- Reluctance to Renew Budgets ers’ ability to twist and turn accordingly. Organizations use budgets to prevent costs from Organizations change constantly. By the time spiraling out of control. But managers may overre- problems emerge, those responsible for planning act as budget depletion highlights what persistence and authorizing the project may have moved on. is costing. More specifically, research has shown Thus, diffusion of responsibility can be a counter- that as budget limits are reached, decision makers force for persistence (Leatherwood & Conlon, 1987; tend to decrease investment (Heath, 1995; Heath & Whyte, 1991). For example, Leatherwood and Con- Soll, 1996). Moreover, experiments with multistage lon (1987) found that freedom to blame a setback on projects have shown that projects that promise to a third party meant less persistence, despite signif- generate net benefits tend to be abandoned. Aban- icant sunk costs. We can infer from this study that donment happens even when additional expendi- a new manager faced with a troubled (but poten- tures at a particular stage would not threaten the tially economically viable) project may abandon it project as a whole (Tan & Yates, 1995). rather than risk subsequently being held responsi- This kind of thinking is irrational because budget ble for both losses out of pocket and the forgone depletion merely tells managers that a certain opportunity cost should the project ultimately fail. amount has been expended; it says nothing about For example, he or she may subdivide a major whether the project is still feasible and worth com- project into less risky mini-projects rather than risk pleting on economic grounds. Indeed, the budget persisting with the more valuable but more uncer- may have been inadequate to begin with. For ex- tain whole (Schoorman, Mayer, Douglas, & Het- ample, most of the cost overruns in the refurbish- rick, 1994). ment of London’s Savoy Hotel were due to contrac- Yet those risks may well be exaggerated. To be tors discovering hidden walls (Blitz, 2010). Given more precise, although a new manager may have the age and size of the building, a bigger budget for no sunk costs to honor (e.g., Ross & Staw, 1991; surprises might have been wise. Yet even sophisti- Simonson & Staw, 1992), he is not without ego. cated decision makers may heed noninformative Ego may lead an incoming manager to devalue his losses (Heath, 1995). predecessor’s work (Taylor, 1980, discusses this Budget depletion can amplify the loss prospect point). For example, research has shown that in other ways. Brockner, Shaw, and Rubin (1979) supervisors may systematically underrate staff if found that decision makers were more likely to quit they disagreed with the appointment (Schoorman, a questionable activity if a decision to remain had 1988) and overrate poorly performing staff they to be made actively versus passively. Budget re- appointed—and make more optimistic predictions newal usually requires an active decision, forcing about their future performance—than staff they managers to confront their options and consider did not personally appoint (Bazerman, Beekun, & opportunity costs. Furthermore, requests for addi- Schoorman, 1982). tional investment may be hotly contested. For in- These studies also imply that a new manager may stance, powerful coalitions competing for scarce systematically underrate a project she did not ini- resources may argue that having expended the bud- tiate, particularly if she disagreed with it (the “not get, a project has had a fair chance to prove itself. invented here” problem). So when it comes to cal- Such arguments may be hard to resist. Indeed, the culating the region of rationality managers may fate of major projects can turn on internal politics unconsciously overestimate future costs and/or (Pfeffer, 1981a). For example, it is thought that underestimate future benefits. Ego may also lead powerful factions within Microsoft may have killed them to overstate the opportunity costs of persis- development of the tablet computer, citing oppor- tence. A new manager may also succumb to reverse tunity costs. confirmation traps, paying more attention to negative 2014 Drummond 437 experience while downplaying or even ignoring the modernize unless it became clear that the metro positive. In short, a new manager may be just as was impossible, which city officials doubted. biased as his predecessor but in the opposite Crises like these highlight loss and uncertainty— direction. important escalation inhibitors. Managers may Even if the original decision makers are still in overreact because the fear sparked by vivid events post, they may not be as irrevocably bound as esca- does not always reflect statistical probability (Kah- lation theorists think. Politically adroit managers may neman, 2011). More specifically, if anecdotal infor- forget their initial enthusiasm for a project, quietly mation is vivid and salient, statistics may well be shuffle responsibility onto other people, and play up ignored, even though they give a more accurate alternative investment opportunities. Hindsight bi- picture of reality (Nisbett & Ross, 1980). For in- ases may also come into play (e.g., Bazerman & stance, in April 2006, the U.K. Ministry of Defense Moore, 2009, p. 38; Lovallo, Clarke, & Camerer, 2012) rolled out a highly ambitious £200 million IT-based as managers assert that they “knew all along” that the payroll platform for the armed forces, known as the project was doomed. Sensing a sea change, others Joint Personnel Administration (JPA) program. may judge it expedient to join the bandwagon. Problems ensued. Some allowances were not paid. Some payments were wrong. Call centers made mistakes. Because of the intense media interest in UNDER WHAT CONDITIONS IS ERRONEOUS the armed forces, those teething troubles made ABANDONMENT MOST LIKELY? headline news (Kelman, Weatherhead, & Weather- Having discussed the forces for abandonment, head, 2009). Yet most payments were correct. Un- the next logical question to ask is this: Under what fortunately, vivid images of soldiers’ wives with no conditions are organizations most likely to give up money obscured this telling statistic. too soon? In practice, a project really fails only when people will no longer support it. Or, as Sauer A Question of Balance? put it, “Failure finally and irreversibly occurs when the level of dissatisfaction [with the project] is such Barring a crisis much may depend on the balance that there is no longer enough support to sustain it” between perceived likelihood of loss and responsi- and all work ceases (1993, p. 27). bility. Figure 1 summarizes the possibilities ad- The most likely scenario is a crisis. For instance, duced from the foregoing exploration of the litera- the explosion at Chernobyl in 1986 destroyed the ture. Recall, escalation is thought to be most myth than nuclear power was safe, thus paving the probable in condition 1, which is characterized by way for dismantling the controversial Shoreham high responsibility coupled with low perceived nuclear plant (Ross & Staw, 1993). Similarly, the likelihood of loss resulting from overconfidence London Ambulance Service abandoned its contro- (e.g., Staw, 1997; Staw & Ross, 1987a). Erroneous versial computerized system when a patient alleg- abandonment seems most probable in condition 2, edly died while waiting for an ambulance (South which is characterized by high risk and low respon- West Thames Regional Health Authority, 1993). sibility. Such conditions may apply where the orig- The patient might have died anyway, the system inal decision makers have moved on so responsi- might have been made to work, but it was aban- bility is diffuse. Recall, diffusion of responsibility doned all the same—possibly erroneously because is associated with less escalation (Dunegan, 1993; of people’s somewhat irrational aversion to loss. Whyte, 1991). For instance, if persistence seems More recently, in 2002, city officials decided to risky, loss-averse decision makers may say to them- build a new metro line in Amsterdam, even though selves, “This project could end in disaster. I am not drilling tunnels below the wooden pillars that sup- going to be blamed if it is canceled now. So why port one of Europe’s oldest cities seemed like folly. take the risk of continuing when I might regret it?” By 2008 several buildings along the new metro Pursuing this line of logic, condition 3, which is route suddenly sank a few centimeters, forcing peo- characterized by low perceived risk coupled with ple to escape through windows and prompting vo- low responsibility, may give rise to “escalating in- ciferous calls to abandon the project. One philoso- decision” (Denis, Dompierre, Langley, & Rouleau, pher, quoted in The Economist (2009), appealed to 2011), where not much happens (except passive civic leaders to stop the project and give the city reinvestment) because there is little fear of loss and back to bikers, but those calls were rebuffed by city little fear of being held accountable to galvanize authorities, who insisted that Amsterdam would decision makers into action. For instance, Denis et 438 The Academy of Management Perspectives November

FIGURE 1 When Erroneous Abandonment Is Most Likely to Occur

al. (2011) found that escalating indecision was on, confidence is likely to be high as risks and strongly associated with diffuse power and the ab- opportunity costs are hidden (e.g., Drummond, sence of leadership. Those conditions might apply 1996). Later, responsibility effects and completion where long timescales are involved, decision mak- may become all important (Conlon & Garland, ers come and go, and problems with the project are 1993). Indeed, Sleesman and colleagues (2012) sug- sporadic. In contrast, decision makers are most gested that at high levels of felt responsibility or likely to get things about right under condition 4, project completion, opportunity costs may actually which is characterized by high risk combined with fuel escalation, as they add to the enormity of the high responsibility. This is where decision makers potential loss. In contrast, the mid-phase is likely are living in the real world. They know what the to be murky. Costs have been incurred, but reve- risks are and that they will be called to account. nues are distant. Risks and opportunity costs Even so, they believe that their role is to overcome emerge, sapping confidence and motivation. Signif- problems despite poor odds (e.g., March & Sha- icantly in experiments, perceived risk decelerates pira, 1987). escalation mainly in the middle phase of project completion (Harvey & Victoravich, 2009; He & Mit- tal, 2007). When Is Erroneous Abandonment Most We also know that as projects near completion, Likely to Happen? the perceived value of the goal can increase, while The middle of a project is probably the most alternatives are undervalued (Ting, 2011). In the vulnerable time for erroneous abandonment. Early middle phase, however, beleaguered managers, 2014 Drummond 439

TABLE 2 Avoiding Value-Destroying Abandonments

Forces for Abandonment Countermeasures Rationale

Loss aversion/cost salience Keep project on track. Uncertainty increases salience of loss potential (Brockner et al., 1979; Rubin & Brockner, 1975) and is liable to provoke negative emotions (Schaubroeck & Davis, 1994; Wong et al., 2006). Reluctance to renew budgets Sacrifice benefits rather than Cost overruns are more salient and more provocative than benefit shortfalls incur overruns. (Fox & Staw, 1979; Northcraft & Wolf, 1984). Avoids issues of budget renewal (Heath, 1995). Perceived risk Keep two sets of books. Optimism sustains motivation in adversity (Taylor & Brown, 1998). Comparing results against realistic expectations may reduce perceived risk (Wong et al., 2006) and reluctance to renew budgets (Heath, 1995). Don’t let failure become Dissonance theory implies that managers act out their expectations (Festinger, self-fulfilling. 1957). Negative information is destructive (Kahneman, 2011). Symbols direct attention to the positive (Pfeffer, 1981b). Awareness of opportunity Evaluate alternatives in advance. Makes it harder to overstate opportunity costs to justify switching. costs/alternatives Adjustments will be anchored in originals (e.g., Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993). Weigh hidden benefits of Real options and indirect advantages of persistence may outweigh opportunity persistence. costs (McAfee et al., 2010). Intolerance of failure Apply “one good reason” Reduces reliance on target setting and other -based heuristics. Enables . managers to scythe through uncertainty (e.g., Bowen, 1987; Simon, 1979) and potential bias and see the forest rather than just the trees. “Lock-in” to publicly stated limits Adopt a Janus face. Managers can reassert their competence, impose control, and manage impressions without becoming publicly committed (Brockner et al., 1981). “Not invented here” Take an external perspective. Enables more robust challenge appraisal of risk and opportunity costs of persistence (Lovallo et al., 2012). Diffusion of responsibility/shifting Burn the boats. Alternatives inhibit escalation (Keil et al., 1995; McCain, 1986); eliminating tides of organization them forces managers to stay the course. Lingering uncertainty Heed intuition. All decisions involving uncertainty risk failure. Intuition can be uncannily accurate (Klein, 1999; Schoemaker & Day, 2009) anxious to exit with honor, may systematically said, “I knew once we [allowed slippage] . . . it overvalue alternatives to justify switching, though would never stop slipping....Weneeded to main- perhaps only to end up jumping from the prover- tain top level confidence, project team morale . . . bial frying pan into the fire. As to what type of and momentum....Similar projects had slipped projects are most vulnerable to erroneous abandon- into oblivion and we would have gone the same ment, Kahneman and Lovallo (1993) suggested way” (Kelman et al., 2009, p. 14). projects big enough to matter but not so big as to If something has to give, managers can sacrifice cause catastrophic losses. The latter are more likely benefits. Loss of benefits merely represents gains to make managers risk-seeking than risk-averse. forgone, whereas overruns amplify the loss pros- pect (Brockner et al., 1979; Northcraft & Wolf, 1984; Rubin & Brockner, 1975). Sacrificing benefits also HOW CAN MANAGERS AVOID VALUE- enables managers to sidestep issues of budget re- DESTROYING ABANDONMENTS? newal (Heath, 1995) and is less likely to provoke Keep the Project on Track potentially debilitating challenges and resistance (Fox & Staw, 1979). For example, rather than ex- Table 2 summarizes the main forces for errone- ceed budgets and timescales, certain JPA benefits ous abandonment mentioned earlier in this paper, concerning access to service records were post- countermeasures, and the rationale for those mea- poned. Although those benefits were part of the sures. Prevention is better than cure. By refusing to râison d’être for JPA, losing them did not unduly countenance overruns, managers may prevent po- harm confidence in the project (Kelman et al., tentially corrosive doubts from gaining a hold in 2009). By contrast, if overruns had been allowed, the first place (e.g., Schaubroeck & Davis, 1994; JPA might have become dogged by failure, ulti- Wong et al., 2006). For instance, in mid-2005, mately becoming long delayed and over budget. nine months from planned rollout, the aforemen- tioned JPA project suffered a setback when some software modules failed an integration test. That Keep Two Sets of Books meant more reengineering than expected. Yet deci- sion makers refused to increase budgets and time- Wildly optimistic plans may not be entirely scales. A senior manager working on the project counterproductive. Delusional optimism can kin- 440 The Academy of Management Perspectives November dle excitement and sustain employees through ad- be (e.g., Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993; Kahneman et versity (Taylor & Brown, 1988). Compiling a second al., 2011). set of predictions firmly grounded in reality may attenuate perceived risk (e.g., Wong et al., 2006) Weigh Hidden Benefits of Persistence and reluctance to renew budgets (e.g., Heath, 1995) by enabling managers to show that the project re- Opportunity costs should be weighed against mains economically defensible. the wider economic benefits of staying the course—including potentially valuable informa- tion (McAfee, Mialon, & Mialon, 2010). More spe- Don’t Let Failure Become Self-Fulfilling cifically, the argument for culling mediocre proj- ects is if they suck resources from good ones. In Dissonance theory implies that managers act out this view, Hewlett-Packard may have been wise their expectations (Festinger, 1957). If delusional to have culled its first tablet computer if it had optimism can be self-fulfilling, so can pessimism little chance of competing against rivals such as (e.g., Seligman, 1975). For example, expecting a the Apple iPad, and if resources could be redi- product launch or a new foreign operation to fail, rected to more profitable possibilities. Yet persis- managers may invest little time preparing, thus tence might have yielded feedback from the mar- guaranteeing failure (Welch & Wiedersheim, 1980). ket that could have informed future design and Similarly, Liesch and colleagues (2011) found that marketing activities. Abandonment stems losses, firms regarding exporting as extremely risky tended but it also stems the flow of information. In ad- to retreat too readily in the face of adversity. Bad dition, firms known to honor onerous contracts experiences can also create failure myopia. That is, may ultimately do better than firms notorious for having declared “never again,” firms forgo poten- walking away (McAfee et al., 2010). For example, tially profitable opportunities to reenter previously Siemens’s decision to abandon several particle- abandoned markets (Javalgi, Deligonul, Dixit, & Ca- therapy cancer centers when costs exceeded ex- vusgil, 2011; Welch & Welch, 2009). Failure begets pectations provoked public hostility (The Econ- failure, but it needn’t. omist, 2013). To break the vicious circle, managers can avoid Likewise, there may be a hidden option value in negative connotations, as they are extremely de- persistence (Leslie & Michaels, 1997). An option is structive (e.g., Dunegan, 1993; Kahneman, 2011), a toehold investment that confers the right (but not and accentuate the positive. For example, “glass the obligation) to take action in the future (e.g., half full” does less psychological damage than Janney & Dess, 2004). For instance, if a troubled “glass half empty.” Adroit manipulation of symbols software project is abandoned in favor of an off-the- can also stop failure from becoming self-fulfilling shelf product, the potentially valuable option of by directing attention to the positive and away from licensing the bespoke software (once it is finished) the negative (Pfeffer, 1981b, discusses symbols). to other firms is lost. Similarly, if a factory build- For example, when JPA faltered, EDS, the contract- ing with adjoining land is sold off, the option of ing firm, ostentatiously flew in their “top technical building on that land is also gone, as are all the experts” (Kelman et al., 2009, p. 18), thereby signi- other options connected with the factory. Before fying that problems were being taken seriously and abandoning a project, managers should consider that something would be done. Language is also what options would be destroyed. Ultimately it symbolically important—for example, “postponed” may be worth switching only for a really large gain rather than “canceled.” (McAfee et al., 2010).

Evaluate Alternative Investment Opportunities Apply the “One Good Reason” Heuristic in Advance Recall that overreliance on targets and the like This is basic good management. More important, it can lead managers to declare failure too soon. In- makes it harder for new managers (and incumbents) voking different heuristics—such as “what is one to exaggerate opportunity costs. Even if those evalu- good reason to persist with this project (Gigerenzer, ations are subsequently revised, revisions are likely to 2008)?” and “what is one good reason to abandon be “anchored” to the original estimates, so they it?” and/or “what is one good reason to pursue should be less outlandish than they otherwise might an alternative?”—can enable managers to scythe 2014 Drummond 441 through uncertain and potentially biased cost/ben- cords had already been transferred. Moreover, many efit analyses and see the forest rather than just the small but important software updates had been made trees—and perhaps even a brilliant opportunity to JPA but not to legacy systems. JPA had to be made staring them in the face. to work because there was simply no other way of Time may be a good reason to abandon a project. getting servicemen and servicewomen paid (Kelman More specifically, in the midst of a troubled proj- et al., 2009). ect, managers should focus on what remains to be done and how long it will take. For instance, a member of the Taurus monitoring group said: Intuition: The Ultimate Heuristic? The City could have swallowed the money bit. They Ultimately, whatever managers decide, outcomes would have said, “OK, there is an overspend of £100 may still turn on luck. Indeed, Napoleon preferred million—let’s fight about who is going to fund that lucky generals to competent ones. But what sepa- because we can see the benefits coming through.” It rates the two? Returning to BP and Bunker Hunt, was the time that killed them all (Drummond, 1996, was the apparently lucky decision a product of p. 164). “seasoned intuition” (Klein, 1999; Schoemaker & Day, 2009) and tacit knowledge (Polanyi, 1962)? Adopt a Janus Face Neither can be codified and transmitted. But both can be uncannily accurate. For example, John Paul No law requires managers to be consistent. The Getty recounts how geologists decreed that the Red ploy of publicly threatening to abandon a troubled Beds region of Oklahoma was barren: project at an unspecified time in the future, while quietly pumping resources into it, enables manag- To me, the area looked as if it might hide oil. Largely ers to strategically manage impressions (e.g., Goff- on a hunch, I decided to see for myself. I began man, 1959) by being seen to reassert control with- drilling in the Red Beds, struck oil and brought in a out binding themselves to publicly stated limits vast new production field. I suspect that by relying upon such non-textbook thought processes and tak- (Brockner et al., 1981). This ploy also enables man- ing attendant risks, the biggest fortunes have been agers to gauge the results of additional investment made—in oil and other endeavors (Adair, 2011, before giving up (Bowen, 1987). p. 16). Having weighed everything, if the issues are Take an External Perspective finely balanced, managers may do well to let their If introducing an outside view can improve proj- intuition have the last word. ect appraisals (Lovallo et al., 2012), it may also promote a more measured assessment of a troubled CONCLUSIONS project. An external perspective may be particu- larly helpful in assessing the risks and opportunity Few complex projects go completely smoothly. costs of persistence, and in challenging any ten- Escalation theorists emphasize the perils of un- dency to undervalue work done by other people. warranted persistence. Yet when it is wise to For instance, if similar projects have succeeded press on despite adversity, doubts and second elsewhere, why abandon this one? thoughts can also be ruinous. More case studies and archival research are needed to advance the synthesis of ideas presented in this paper. In Burn the Boats particular, we need to better understand how the Recall that alternatives can undermine confidence twin, but contradictory, forces of in an existing project (e.g., McCain, 1986; Northcraft and overconfidence may play out in different & Neale, 1986). Alternatives may also make commit- contexts when important ventures are not going ment seem less irrevocable (McCain, 1986) and pro- according to plan. What conditions are most con- mote regret as decision makers compare what is with ducive to erroneous persistence, and what condi- what might have been (e.g., Kahneman, 2001). Elim- tions are most conducive to erroneous abandon- inating alternatives forces people to stay the course ment? A particularly fruitful avenue may be to (e.g., Ariely, 2009; Drummond, 2012). For example, explore whether and to what extent managers when JPA escalated into a crisis, there was no ques- think about opportunity costs, how they think tion of reverting to legacy systems. Thousands of re- about them, and how they evaluate alternative 442 The Academy of Management Perspectives November projects at different levels of completion. Inves- As for which is worse, giving up too soon or too tigating old questions from a new angle may also late, the answer may be neither. Plunging boldly prove rewarding. For instance, if, as mentioned through adversity may mean that costs are higher earlier in this paper, negative emotions such as than expected and benefits far fewer. But the end anticipated regret and fear of blame can negate product may be serviceable nonetheless. Persis- potentially potent responsibility effects, when tence in adversity may even lead to the stars. might the reverse be true? These questions will be Conversely, calling a decisive halt stops losses left for future research. and enables remaining resources to be redirected As for this paper, we are left with several impor- to more profitable possibilities. In contrast, man- tant insights. First, educating managers to avoid agers who stall and/or persist halfheartedly may foolhardy inconsistency means recognizing that only prolong the psychological pain and deepen some of the standard measures for curbing escala- the loss. For all that has been said about costly tion, such as changing project managers, may am- decision error—be it persistence or abandon- plify the risk of erroneous abandonment. Although ment—is the wrong decision better than no managers should not be afraid to impose control decision? and make necessary changes, they should be aware of possible side effects. The second, and perhaps more important, in- REFERENCES sight for a more nuanced understanding of esca- lation is why doubts and second thoughts can be Adair, J. (2011). 100 greatest ideas for smart decision- ruinous. More specifically, in practice conflicting making. Chichester, UK: Capstone. forces may largely cancel one another out. If so, Anderson, C. J. (2003). The psychology of doing nothing: decisions may turn the residual balance of forces Forms of decision avoidance result from reason and left in the equation. More often than not, that emotion. Psychological Bulletin, 129(1), 139–167. balance may favor persistence, but perhaps not Ariely, D. (2009). Predictably irrational. New York: always the reckless reinvestment in a project that HarperCollins. is already doomed—as envisaged by escalation Arkes, H. R., & Blumer, C. (1985). The psychology of sunk theorists. Unwilling to admit failure, but equally costs. Organizational Behavior and Human Perfor- fearful of compounding the loss, conflicted mana- mance, 35(1), 124–140. gers may become trapped in the middle. That is, Bacharach, S. B. (1989). Organizational theories: Some they may reinvest enough to keep the project alive criteria for evaluation. Academy of Management Re- and stave off the impression of failure, but not view, 14, 496–515. nearly enough to maximize the probability of suc- Bazerman, M. H., Beekun, R. I., & Schoorman, F. D. cess. In other words, conflicted managers may (1982). Performance evaluation in a dynamic con- doom potentially successful projects by reinvesting text: A laboratory study of the impact of the prior too little. commitment to the Ratee. Journal of Applied Psy- And maybe too late as well. Experiments usually chology, 67, 873–876. involve forced choices, yet aversion to loss is asso- Bazerman, M. H., & Moore, D. A. (2009). Judgment in ciated with decision avoidance (Anderson, 2003). managerial decision-making. New York: Wiley. Indeed, field studies have shown that faltering ven- tures can drift for months and even years (Denis et Benito, G. R. G., & Welch, L. S. (1997). De-international- al., 2011; Drummond, 1994; Mähring & Keil, 2008). ization. Management International Review, 37(2), 7–25. Avoidance affords temporary psychological shelter but at greater cost. For example, managers may Berry, H. (2013). When do firms divest foreign opera- demand information that takes weeks to produce tions? Organization Science, 24, 246–261. but will not help to resolve the dilemma. We need Blitz, R. (2010, October 8). Savoy reopens after £220 mil- to know more about when managers are most prone lion revamp. Financial Times. Available at http:// to avoidance and what forms of avoidance they www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/34545190-d30e-11df-9ae9- tend to favor. For instance, do measures ostensibly 00144feabdc0.html intended to curb escalation, such as limit setting, Boulding, W., Morgan, R., & Staelin, R. (1997). Pulling sometimes mask decision avoidance—a ploy to the plug to stop new product drain. Journal of Mar- postpone the inevitable? If so, avoidance might be keting Research, 34, 164–176. more prevalent than we think. Bowen, M. G. (1987). The escalation phenomenon recon- 2014 Drummond 443

sidered: Decision dilemmas or decision errors? Dunegan, K. J. (1993). Framing, cognitive models and Academy of Management Review, 12, 52–66. image theory: Toward an understanding of a glass Bragger, J. D., Bragger, D., Hantula, D. A., & Kirnan, J. half full. Journal of Applied Psychology, 78, 419– (1998). Hysteresis and uncertainty: The effect of un- 503. certainty on delays to exit decisions. Journal of Ap- Fay, S. (1982). Beyond greed. New York: Viking. plied Psychology, 88, 6–14. Felsted, A. (2013, April 8). Tesco counts cost of failed US ven- Brockner, J. (1992). The escalation of commitment to a ture. Financial Times. Available at http://www.ft.com/ failing course of action: Toward theoretical progress. intl/cms/s/0/a4aa2fbc-a077-11e2-a6e1-00144feabdc0. Academy of Management Review, 17, 39–61. html Brockner, J., Rubin, J. Z., & Lang, E. (1981). Face-saving Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. and entrapment. Journal of Experimental Social Psy- Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press. chology, 17(1), 68–79. Flyvbjerg, B., Garbuio, M., & Lovallo, D. (2009). Delusion Brockner, J., Shaw, M. C., & Rubin, J. Z. (1979). Factors and deception in large infrastructure projects. Cali- affecting withdrawal from an escalating conflict: fornia Management Review, 52(2), 170–193. Quitting before it’s too late. Journal of Experimental Fox, F., & Staw, B. M. (1979). The trapped administrator: Social Psychology, 17(5), 492–503. The effects of job insecurity and policy resistance Butler, S. (2012, December 9). Fresh, but not so easy: Tesco upon commitment to a course of action. Administra- joins a long list of British failure in America. The Ob- tive Science Quarterly, 24, 449–471. server. Available at http://www.theguardian.com/ Garland, H. (1990). Throwing good money after bad: The business/2012/dec/09/fresh-not-easy-tesco-british- effect of sunk costs on the decision to escalate com- failure-america. mitment to an ongoing project. Journal of Applied Camerer, C. F., & Weber, R. A. (1999). The econometrics Psychology, 75, 728–731. and behavioral economics of commitment: A re-ex- Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Why heuristics work. Perspectives amination of Staw and Hoang’s NBA data. Journal of on Psychological Science, 3(1), 20–29. Economic Behavior and Organization, 39(1), 59–82. Gigerenzer, G., & Gaissmaier, W. (2011). Heuristic deci- Conlon, E. J., & Garland, H. (1993). The role of project sion making. Annual Review of Psychology, 62, 451– completion information in resource allocation deci- 482. sions. Academy of Management Journal, 36, 402– Goffman, E. (1959). The presentation of self in everyday 413. life. New York: Doubleday. Conlon, E. J., & Parks, J. M. (1987). Information requests Harvey, P., & Victoravich, L. M. (2009). The influence of in the context of escalation. Journal of Applied Psy- forward-looking antecedents, uncertainty, and antic- chology, 72, 344–350. ipatory emotions on project escalation. Decision Sci- Decker, C., & Mellewigt, T. (2007). Thirty years after ences, 40, 759–782. Michael E. Porter: What do we know about business He, X., & Mittal, V. (2007). The effect of decision risk and exit? Academy of Management Perspectives, 21, 41– project stage on escalation of commitment. Organi- 55. zational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, Denis, J. L., Dompierre, G., Langley, A., & Rouleau, L. 103, 225–237. (2011). Escalating indecision: Between reification Heath, C. (1995). Escalation and de-escalation of commit- and strategic ambiguity. Organization Science, 22, ment in response to sunk costs: The role of budgeting 225–244. in accounting. Organizational Behavior and Human Drummond, H. (1994). Too little too late: A case study of Decision Processes, 62, 38–54. escalation in decision-making. Organization Stud- Heath, C., & Soll, B. (1996). Mental budgeting and con- ies, 15, 509–605. sumer decisions. Journal of Consumer Research, 23, Drummond, H. (1995). De-escalation in decision-making: 40–52. A case of a disastrous partnership. Journal of Man- Janney, J. J., & Dess, G. G. (2004). Can real-options anal- agement Studies, 32, 265–281. ysis improve decision-making? Promises and pit- Drummond, H. (1996). Escalation in decision-making: falls. Academy of Management Executive, 18(4), 60– The tragedy of Taurus. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univer- 75. sity Press. Javalgi, R. G., Deligonul, S., Dixit, A., & Cavusgil, S. T. Drummond, H., & Hodgson, J. (2011). Escalation in deci- (2011). International market re-entry: A review and sion-making: Behavioral economics in business. research framework. International Business Review, Farnham, UK: Gower. 20, 377–393. 444 The Academy of Management Perspectives November

Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. London: tional entrepreneurship studies: Review and concep- Penguin. tual development. Management International Re- Kahneman, D., & Lovallo, D. (1993). Timid choices and view, 51, 851–873. bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk tak- Loewenstein, G. F., Weber, E. U., Hsee, C. K., & Welch, N. ing. Management Science, 39, 17–31. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin, Kahneman, D., Lovallo, D., & Sibony, O. (2011). Before 127(2), 267–286. you make that big decision. Harvard Business Re- Lovallo, D., Clarke, C., & Camerer, C. (2012). Robust view, 89(6), 51–60. analogizing and the outside view: Two empirical Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). : An tests of case-based decision-making. Strategic Man- analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, agement Journal, 33, 496–512. 263–291. Lovallo, D., & Kahneman, D. (2003). Delusions of success: Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1982). The psychology of How optimism undermines executives’ decisions. preferences. Scientific American, 246(1), 162–170. Harvard Business Review, 81(7), 57–63. Kavanagh, M. (2013, April 17). Tullow hit by dry well in Lovallo, D., Viguerie, P., Uhlaner, R., & Horn, J. (2007). French Guiana. Financial Times. Available at http:// Deals without delusions. Harvard Business Review, www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/75b8da38-a779-11e2-bfcd- 85(12), 92–99. 00144feabdc0.html Mähring, M., & Keil, M. (2008). Information technology Keil, M., & Mähring, M. (2010). Is your project turning project escalation: A processes model. Decision Sci- into a black hole? California Management Review, ences, 39, 239–272. 53(1), 6–28. March, J. G., & Shapira, Z. (1987). Managerial perspec- Keil, M., & Robey, D. (1999). Turning around troubled tives on risk and risk taking. Management Science, software projects: An exploratory study of de-esca- 33, 1404–1418. lation of commitment to failing courses of action. McAfee, R. P., Mialon, H. M., & Mialon, S. H. (2010). Do Journal of Management Information Systems, 15(4), sunk costs matter? Economic Inquiry, 48, 323–336. 63–87. McCain, B. E. (1986). Continuing investment under con- Keil, M., Truex, D. P., III, & Mixon, R. (1995). The effects ditions of failure: A laboratory study of the limits of of and project completion on information escalation. Journal of Applied Psychology, 71, 280– technology project escalation. IEEE Transactions on 284. Engineering Management, 40, 372–381. Monteagre, R., & Keil, M. (2000). De-escalating informa- Kelman, S., Weatherhead, A. J., III, & Weatherhead, R. W. tion technology projects: Lessons from the Denver (2009). A different kind of partnership: The UK’s Ministry of Defense and EDS develop the Joint Per- International Airport. MIS Quarterly, 24, 417–447. sonnel Administration program (JPA) (Kennedy Moon, H., & Conlon, D. E. (2002). From acclaim to blame: School of Government Case Program, CR16-09- Evidence of a person sensitivity decision bias. Jour- 1900-0, 1–22). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. nal of Applied Psychology, 87(1), 33–42. Klein, G. (1999). Sources of power: How people make Nisbett, R. E., & Ross, L. (1980). Human inference: Strat- decisions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. egies and shortcomings of social judgment. Engle- Ku, G. (2008). Learning to de-escalate: The effects of wood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. regret in escalation of commitment. Organizational Northcraft, G. B., & Neale, M. A. (1986). Opportunity Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 105, 221– costs and framing of resource allocation decisions. 232. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Pro- Kuvaas, B., & Selart, M. (2004). Effects of attribute fram- cesses, 37, 348–355. ing on cognitive processing and evaluation. Organi- Northcraft, G., & Wolf, G. (1984). Dollars sense and sunk zational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, costs: A life cycle model of resource allocation deci- 95, 198–207. sions. Academy of Management Review, 9, 225–234. Leatherwood, M. L., & Conlon, E. J. (1987). Diffusibility Pfeffer, J. (1981a). Power in organizations. Boston: Pitman. of blame: Effects of persistence on a project. Acad- emy of Management Journal, 30, 836–487. Pfeffer, J. (1981b). Management as symbolic action: The creation and maintenance of organizational para- Leslie, K. J., & Michaels, M. P. (1997). The real power of digms. In L. L. Cummings & B. M. Staw (Eds.), Re- real options. McKinsey Quarterly, 3, 4–22. search in organizational behavior: An annual series Liesch, P. W., Welch, L. S., & Buckley, P. J. (2011). Risk of essays and critical reviews (pp. 1–52). Greenwich, and uncertainty in internationalization and interna- CT: JAI Press. 2014 Drummond 445

Polanyi, M. (1962). Personal knowledge: Towards a post- ary). Report of the inquiry into the London ambulance critical philosophy. New York: Harper Torch. service. London: Author. Available at www.0.cs.ucl.ac. Porter, M. E. (1976). Please note location of nearest exit. uk/staff/A.Finkelstein/las/lascase0.9.pdf. California Management Review, 19(2), 21–33. Stacey, K. (2013, August 18). Cost of HS2 could hit Ross, J., & Staw, B. M. (1991). Managing escalation pro- £80 billion claims Institute of Economic Affairs, Fi- cesses in organizations. Journal of Management Is- nancial Times. Available at http://www.ft.com/intl/ sues, 3, 15–30. cms/s/0/452a950e-07e7-11e3-badc-00144feabdc0. html Ross, J., & Staw, B. M. (1993). Organizational escalation and exit: Lessons from the Shoreham nuclear power Staw, B. M. (1976). Knee-deep in the big muddy: A study plant. Academy of Management Journal, 36, 701– of escalating commitment to a chosen course of ac- 732. tion. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 16, 27–44. Rubin, J. Z., & Brockner, J. (1975). Factors affecting en- trapment in waiting situations: The Rosencrantz and Staw, B. M. (1997). Escalation research: An update and Guildenstern effect. Journal of Personality and So- appraisal. In Z. Shapira (Ed.), Organizational deci- cial Psychology, 31, 1054–1063. sion making (pp. 191–215). Cambridge, UK: Cam- bridge University Press. Sauer, C. (1993). Why information systems fail: A case study approach. Henley, UK: Alfred Waller. Staw, B. M., & Fox, F. V. (1977). Escalation: The deter- minants of commitment to a chosen course of action. Schaubroeck, J., & Davis, E. (1994). Prospect theory pre- Human Relations, 30, 431–450. dictions when escalation is not the only chance to recover sunk costs. Organizational Behavior and Hu- Staw, B. M., & Ross, J. (1978). Commitment to a policy man Decision Processes, 57, 59–82. decision: A multi-theoretical perspective. Adminis- trative Science Quarterly, 23, 40–46. Schoemaker, P. J. H., & Day, G. S. (2009). How to make sense of weak signals. MIT Sloan Management Re- Staw, B. M., & Ross, J. (1987a). Behavior in escalation view, 50(3), 81–89. situations: Antecedents, prototypes and solutions. In L. L. Cummings & B. M. Staw (Eds.), Research in Schoorman, F. D. (1988). Escalation bias in performance organization behavior: An annual series of essays appraisals: An unintended consequence of supervi- and critical reviews (pp. 39–78). Greenwich, CT: JAI sor participation in hiring decisions. Journal of Ap- Press. plied Psychology, 73, 58–62. Staw, B. M., & Ross, J. (1987b). Knowing when to pull the Schoorman, F. D., Mayer, R. C., Douglas, C. A., & Hetrick, plug. Harvard Business Review, 65(2), 65–72. C. T. (1994). Escalation of commitment and the fram- ing effect: An empirical investigation. Journal of Ap- Stross, R. (2012, December 8). Billion-dollar flop: Air plied Social Psychology, 24, 509–528. Force stumbles on software plan. New York Times. Available at http://www.nytimes.com/2012/12/ Seligman, M. E. P. (1975). Helplessness: On depres- 09/technology/air-force-stumbles-over-software- sion, development and death. San Francisco: W.H. modernization-project.html Freeman. Tabuchi, H. (2014, May 27). Sony’s bread and butter? Simonson, I., & Staw, B. M. (1992). Deescalation strate- It’s not electronics. New York Times. Available at gies: A comparison of techniques for reducing com- http://www.nytimes.com/2013/05/28/business/ mitment to losing courses of action. Journal of Ap- global/sonys-bread-and-butter-its-not-electronics. plied Psychology, 77, 419–426. html Sitkin, S. B., & Pablo, A. L. (1992). Re-conceptualizing Taleb, N. (2008). The black swan: The impact of the the determinants of risk behavior. Academy of Man- highly improbable. London: Penguin. agement Review, 17, 9–39. Tan, H.-T., & Yates, J. F. (1995). Sunk cost effects: The Sitkin, S. B., & Weingart, L. R. (1995). Determinants of influences of instruction and future return estimates. risky decision-making behavior: A test of the medi- Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Pro- ating role of risk perceptions and propensity. Acad- emy of Management Journal, 38, 1573–1592. cesses, 63, 311–319. Sleesman, D. J., Conlon, D. E., McNamara, G., & Miles, Taylor, S. E. (1980). Positive illusions. New York: Basic J. E. (2012). Cleaning up the big muddy: A meta- Books. analytic review of the determinants of escalation of Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well- commitment. Academy of Management Journal, 55, being: A social psychological perspective on mental 541–562. health. Psychological Bulletin, 103(2), 193–210. South West Thames Regional Health Authority (1993, Febru- Teger, A. I. (1980). Too much invested to quit: The 446 The Academy of Management Perspectives November

psychology of the escalation of conflict. New York: sions under escalation situations. Applied Psychol- Pergamon. ogy: An International Review, 54, 584–607. The Economist. (2009, February 15). Amsterdam’s trou- Wong, K. F., & Kwong, J. Y. (2007). The role of antici- bled metro: A big dig. The Economist. Available at pated regret in escalation of commitment. Journal of http://www.economist.com/node/13061969 Applied Psychology, 92(2), 282–297. The Economist. (2013, August 3). Siemens: Crisis, what Wong, K. F., Yik, M., & Kwong, J. Y. (2006). Understand- crisis? The Economist. Available at http://www. ing the emotional aspects of escalation of commit- economist.com/news/business/21582514-german- ment: The role of negative affect. Journal of Applied engineering-giants-new-boss-may-struggle-get-it- Psychology, 91(2), 282–297. shape-crisis-what-crisis Wortman, C. B., & Brehm, J. W. (1975). Responses to Ting, H. (2011). The effects of goal distance and value in uncontrollable outcomes: An integration of reac- escalation of commitment. Current Psychology, 30, tance theory and learned helplessness. In L. Berkow- 93–104. itz (Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychol- Welch, C. L., & Welch, L. S. (2009). Re-internationaliza- ogy (pp. 277–336). Washington, DC: Academic Press. tion: Exploration and conceptualization. Interna- Zhang, L., & Baumeister, R. F. (2006). Your money or tional Business Review, 18, 567–577. your self-esteem: Threatened egotism promotes Welch, L. S., & Wiedersheim, P. (1980). Initial exports—a costly entrapment in losing endeavors. Personality marketing failure? Journal of Management Studies, and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32(7), 881–893. 17, 333–344. Whetten, D. A. (1989). What constitutes a theoretical contribution? Academy of Management Review, 14, 490–495. Helga Drummond ([email protected]) is a profes- Whyte, G. (1986). Escalating commitment to a course of sor of decision sciences at the University of Liverpool action: A re-interpretation. Academy of Management Management School and Gresham Visiting Professor of Review, 11, 311–321. Business. She earned her PhD in organization behavior from Leeds University. Other research interests include Whyte, G. (1991). Diffusion of responsibility: Effects on power, symbols, and symbolic behavior in organizations, the escalation tendency. Journal of Applied Psychol- and theory building. ogy, 76, 408–415. Wong, K. F. E. (2005). The role of risk in making deci- Copyright of Academy of Management Perspectives is the property of Academy of Management and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.