What Did We Learn from the Financial Crisis, the Great Recession, and the Pathetic Recovery?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

What Did We Learn from the Financial Crisis, the Great Recession, and the Pathetic Recovery? What Did We Learn from the Financial Crisis, the Great Recession, and the Pathetic Recovery? by Alan S. Blinder, Princeton University Griswold Center for Economic Policy Studies Working Paper No. 243, November 2014 This paper is based on a presentation at The Fourth Annual AEA Conference on Teaching and Research in Economic Education, Washington, DC, on May 30, 2014. This paper comes in three parts. Part 1 reviews a few pertinent facts about the stunning economic events that have occurred in the United States (and elsewhere) since 2007. I choose these particular facts from among many for their relevance to the rest of the paper. The next two parts take up, first, some of the key lessons that we professional economists should have learned from the crisis and its aftermath and, second, some important lessons for teaching economics--especially but not exclusively macroeconomics. The two categories of lessons overlap a bit. But is it perhaps surprising how different they are. 1. A few pertinent facts The Great Recession that began, according to NBER dating,1 in the final month of 2007 was the worst in this nation’s history since the 1930s.2 The peak-to-trough decline in real GDP was 4¼ percent, compared to less than 2½ percent for the deep 1981-1982 recession. The corresponding peak-to-trough decline in payroll employment was even larger: a heart-rending 6.3 percent, versus just 3.1 percent in 1981-1982. Furthermore, in sharp contrast to the notion that severe recessions are followed by sharp recoveries, the recovery that started in mid-2009 has been one of the most anemic on record, with an average compound growth rate (through 2014:3) of just 2.2 percent. It wasn’t until 2011:2 that real GDP returned to its 2007:4 level, and it wasn’t until May 2014 (the month of the AEA conference) that payroll employment re-attained its January 2008 peak. At the time of the conference, the CBO was estimating a GDP gap of 4.5 percent of real GDP in 2013. All in all, it’s been a miserable performance. But it would have been much worse had Congress, the US Treasury, and the Federal Reserve not taken a series of extraordinary actions.3 After much prodding and a Munchian scream from the stock market in 2008, Congress held its collective nose and passed the much-reviled Troubled Assets Relief 1 I prefer to date this recession from September 15, 2008, the day Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy protection. But I’m not a bureau. 2 Official quarterly GDP data are not available for the 1930s, but from what we know, the 1937-1938 recession was far worse than the 2007-2009 recession. The latest recession is noticeably worse than any other post-World War II recession. 3 Mark Zandi and I (2010) estimated that, without these actions, real GDP in 2011 would have been $1.8 trillion lower and the unemployment rate would have been 6.5 points higher. 2 Program (TARP), which was quickly labeled a “$700 billion bank bailout” although it was neither.4 Months later, under the Obama administration, Congress passed a huge fiscal stimulus over almost unanimous Republican opposition. The Federal Reserve put a lot of taxpayer money on the line to rescue Bear Stearns and AIG (but not Lehman Brothers). It created an alphabet soup of lending facilities to extend credit to banks and nonbanks alike in ways previously thought unimaginable—and to bring the moribund markets for commercial paper and mortgage-backed securities back to life. It expanded its balance sheet from under $1 trillion to about $4.5 trillion through a variety of programs known as “quantitative easing” (QE). And it led innovative, multi-agency “stress tests” of the nation’s largest (and, in a few cases, shakiest) financial institutions in the spring of 2009. The Treasury put Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into conservatorship, lobbied for and administered the TARP and the GM and Chrysler bailouts, creatively (also legally?) used the Exchange Stabilization Fund to guarantee assets in money market mutual funds (which were experiencing runs), announced the bank stress tests, and more.5 The FDIC took the amazing step of guaranteeing certain long-term non- deposit liabilities of banks and nonbanks. This flurry of activity constituted the most interventionist set of economic policies in the U.S. since mobilization for total war in the 1940s. And it worked. There was no Great Depression 2.0; we did not have to nationalize the banks; once the dust settled, the government turned a sizable profit on its rescue operations.6 Yet here is what I call the policy paradox:7 Most if not all of these policies, though successful, have been vilified; they helped create an anti-government backlash with which we are still living. 4 Outstandings under TARP never topped about $425 billion, and the bank “bailout” consisted of loans that were and stock purchases of stock that turned a profit. 5 One example: the mostly-unsuccessful and, I would argue, half-hearted attempts to reduce home mortgage foreclosures. 6 It is frequently objected that this profit calculation is bogus because an actuarial cost should be recorded for possible losses to taxpayers. That’s true, and CBO scored TARP that way originally. A January 2009 CBO estimate placed the average subsidy value at 26% of the (early) outlays. See CBO (2009). But the actions themselves prevented losses from occurring—or at least reduced the odds severely. Besides, had substantial taxpayer money been lost, do you think anyone would be arguing that we should count only the actuarial expectation of loss? 7 See Blinder (2013), especially Chapter 13. 3 An anti-government backlash? Yes, but it was more particularly a backlash against the Democratic Party. Once Barack Obama became president, Republicans opposed virtually every anti-recession measure, attacked the Fed, and called for fiscal austerity. Then they swept to impressive electoral victories in the 2010 and 2014 midterm elections. (In between, President Obama somehow won reelection.) The Tea Party, in particular, had its origins in the famous “Rick Santelli rant” against the Obama administration’s (weak) foreclosure mitigation program. The hated TARP, which was suggested by and passed under President George W. Bush, became, in the public eye, an Obama policy.8 One piece of this backlash was directed at Keynesian economics—not at any of the fancy stuff, but at the most elementary ideas. Keynesian teaching in textbooks since the 1940s has held that both monetary stimulus (lower interest rates, more money creation) and fiscal stimulus (tax cuts, government spending) can mitigate recessions. Many Keynesian economists, including me, go on to the normative position that central banks and governments should use monetary and fiscal policies for this purpose. And in this particular mega-recession, countries all over the world did stimulate their economies, to good effect. Focusing on the United States, Congress enacted a modest-sized tax cut (about 1 percent of GDP) in 2008 and a massive stimulus package (about 5 percent of GDP) early in 2009. Roughly a third of that package was tax cuts. Some true Keynesians, such as my colleague Paul Krugman, criticized the 2009 stimulus as inadequate. But it was large by any historical standard.9 Because of the stimulus and the huge recession, the federal fiscal deficit rocketed to about 10 percent of GDP—a shockingly large number for the USA. And largely because of that huge deficit, a severe political backlash against “deficit spending” (but perhaps not against tax cuts) developed and, more or less, took over the fiscal policy debate in the U.S.—which by 2010 was focused on reducing the deficit. By 2013, the fiscal drag was extreme, perhaps in the range of 2 percentage points of GDP growth. 8 For example, a Pew (2010) poll in 2010 found that only 34% of Americans (34%) said the TARP was enacted under President Bush administration; 47% said it was passed under President Obama. 9 Krugman’s point is that the need was huge. The stimulus was not large enough to fill the entire GDP gap. 4 The Fed, for its part, pulled out all the stops. After some initial hesitancy, it dropped the federal funds rate to near zero by December 2008 and then turned to a variety of “unconventional” monetary policies like massive lending, quantitative easing, and explicit forward guidance. As noted, the size of the Fed’s balance sheet rose by about a factor of five. Even more stunningly, banks’ holdings of excess reserves—which, textbooks teach, are normally zero—skyrocketed from about zero when Lehman failed to about $800 billion soon thereafter and eventually to an astounding $2.6 trillion. As all this was happening, critics began warning—even while the crisis was still white hot—that such hyper-expansionary monetary policies sowed the seeds of future inflation. Some of the criticisms reflected abysmal ignorance. For example, strident objectors to “big government” seemed just to discover that the Fed had enormous discretionary power to “create money”--and they didn’t like that. But other criticisms, such as those from Allan Meltzer (2009) and John Taylor (2009), hardly reflected ignorance. These and other experts urged the Fed to cease and desist from its extraordinary efforts to fight the Great Recession. All of this adds up to a very big deal--indeed, to several very big deals: earth-shattering economic events, stupendously large and sometimes innovative policy responses, and a severe backlash that altered the US political landscape for years to come. Hmm. Sounds a bit like the Great Depression and the New Deal.
Recommended publications
  • Quantitative Easing and Inequality: QE Impacts on Wealth and Income Distribution in the United States After the Great Recession
    University of Puget Sound Sound Ideas Economics Theses Economics, Department of Fall 2019 Quantitative Easing and Inequality: QE impacts on wealth and income distribution in the United States after the Great Recession Emily Davis Follow this and additional works at: https://soundideas.pugetsound.edu/economics_theses Part of the Finance Commons, Income Distribution Commons, Macroeconomics Commons, Political Economy Commons, and the Public Economics Commons Recommended Citation Davis, Emily, "Quantitative Easing and Inequality: QE impacts on wealth and income distribution in the United States after the Great Recession" (2019). Economics Theses. 108. https://soundideas.pugetsound.edu/economics_theses/108 This Dissertation/Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics, Department of at Sound Ideas. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Theses by an authorized administrator of Sound Ideas. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Quantitative Easing and Inequality: QE impacts on wealth and income distribution in the United States after the Great Recession Emily Davis Abstract In response to Great Recession, the Federal Reserve implemented quantitative easing. Quantitative easing (QE) aided stabilization of the economy and reduction of the liquidity trap. This research evaluates the correlation between QE implementation and increased inequality through the recovery of the Great Recession. The paper begins with an evaluation of the literature focused on QE impacts on financial markets, wages, and debt. Then, the paper conducts an analysis of QE impacts on income, household wealth, corporations and the housing market. The analysis found that the changes in wealth distribution had a significant impact on increasing inequality. Changes in wages were not the prominent cause of changes in GINI post-recession so changes in existing wealth appeared to be a contributing factor.
    [Show full text]
  • Drastic Times Page 1 of 3 Economist.Com 1/8/2009
    Economist.com Page 1 of 3 Economics focus Drastic times Jan 8th 2009 From The Economist print edition Past crises inspire little confidence about the outcome of this one for America THE good news, said Alan Blinder of Princeton University to a crowded hall on the opening day of this year’s gathering of the American Economic Association (AEA) in San Francisco, is that the stockmarket rallied yesterday. The bad news, he joked, is that it bounced on hopes that the economy’s problems would be solved at the AEA meetings. No such luck. The prevailing mood at this year’s event was one of despair, not hope. The tone of the three-day conference, which ran between January 3rd and 5th, was set on its first morning when Kenneth Rogoff of Harvard University outlined the results of new research conducted with Carmen Reinhart of the University of Maryland. The paper*, a sequel to work presented at the 2008 conference, looks at the aftermath of past financial meltdowns to gauge just how bad America’s recession might be. The analysis is based on 14 “severe” banking busts, including the Depression as well as the more recent “big- five” crises in the rich world—Spain in the late 1970s, Norway in 1987, and Finland, Japan and Sweden in the early 1990s. The sample also includes seven emerging-market crises that were left out of the earlier analysis for fear of appearing too alarmist. A year on, the authors have no such qualms. The hubristic belief in America that “we don’t have financial crises” is now obviously false, said Mr Rogoff.
    [Show full text]
  • QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit
    QE Equivalence to Interest Rate Policy: Implications for Exit Samuel Reynard∗ Preliminary Draft - January 13, 2015 Abstract A negative policy interest rate of about 4 percentage points equivalent to the Federal Reserve QE programs is estimated in a framework that accounts for the broad money supply of the central bank and commercial banks. This provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (relative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance. JEL classification: E52; E58; E51; E41; E43 Keywords: Quantitative Easing; Negative Interest Rate; Exit; Monetary policy transmission; Money Supply; Banking ∗Swiss National Bank. Email: [email protected]. The views expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect those of the Swiss National Bank. I am thankful to Romain Baeriswyl, Marvin Goodfriend, and seminar participants at the BIS, Dallas Fed and SNB for helpful discussions and comments. 1 1. Introduction This paper presents and estimates a monetary policy transmission framework to jointly analyze central banks (CBs)’ asset purchase and interest rate policies. The negative policy interest rate equivalent to QE is estimated in a framework that ac- counts for the broad money supply of the CB and commercial banks. The framework characterises how standard monetary policy, setting an interbank market interest rate or interest on reserves (IOR), has to be adjusted to account for the effects of the CB’s broad money injection. It provides a quantitative estimate of how much higher (rel- ative to pre-QE) the interbank interest rate will have to be set during the exit, for a given central bank’s balance sheet, to obtain a desired monetary policy stance.
    [Show full text]
  • Researchupdate
    www.newyorkfed.org/research ReseResearcharchUUPDATEPDATE federalFederal reserve reserve bank bank of of new new york York ■ ■ Number Number 2, 3, 2012 2009 Research and Statistics Group www.newyorkfed.org/researchwww.newyorkfed.org/research Two Research Series Examine Recent Changes in Banking n July, the Research Group published a special The five articles that follow explore the idea of volume of the Economic Policy Review (EPR) bank adaptation in more depth, presenting arguments and a companion series of Liberty Street and findings associated with the volume’s emphasis on Economics blog posts on the evolution of intermediation roles and changes in bank structure. Ibanking since the advent of asset securitization. In “The Rise of the Originate-to-Distribute The project came out of discussions within the Model and the Role of Banks in Financial Intermedia- Group about “shadow banks” and their role in the tion,” Vitaly Bord and João Santos show that banks 2007-09 financial crisis. The consensus was that it is indeed play a much more important part in lending no longer obvious what banks really do and to what than what the balance sheet suggests. Moreover, bank extent they are still central to the process of financial actions have actually spurred the growth of shadow intermediation. Getting a better under- banks involved in the subsequent steps of the credit The main finding standing of these issues is important from intermediation chain. of the studies an academic perspective, but the insights Benjamin Mandel, Donald Morgan, and is that financial gained from the exercise could also prove Chenyang Wei next analyze the importance of banks intermediation is in useful in a practical sense for policymakers.
    [Show full text]
  • HOW DID QUANTITATIVE EASING REALLY WORK? a New Methodology for Measuring the Fed’S Impact on Financial Markets
    HOW DID QUANTITATIVE EASING REALLY WORK? A New Methodology for Measuring the Fed’s Impact on Financial Markets Ramin Toloui Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research [email protected] SIEPR Working Paper No. 19-032 November 2019 ABSTRACT This paper introduces a new methodology for measuring the impact of unconventional policies. Specifically, the paper examines how such policies reshaped market perceptions of how the Fed would behave in the future—not merely the expected path for policy rates, but how the central bank would adjust that path in response to different combinations of future inflation and growth. In short, it studies how quantitative easing affected investor beliefs about the future policy reaction function. The paper (1) proposes a novel model of market expectations for the central bank’s future policy reaction function based on the Taylor Rule; (2) shows that empirical estimates of the model exhibit structural breaks that coincide with innovations in unconventional policies; and (3) finds that such policy innovations were associated with regime shifts in the behavior of 10-year U.S. Treasury yields, as well as unusual performance in risk assets such as credit spreads and equities. These findings provide evidence that a key causal channel for unconventional policies was via their impact on market expectations for the Fed’s future policy reaction function. These shifts in expectations, in turn, appear to have had larger, more persistent, and more pervasive effects across financial markets than found in previous studies. Monetary economics today is obsessed with balance sheets—and rightfully so. More than ten years after the global financial crisis, policy interest rates remain exceptionally low in much of the industrialized world.
    [Show full text]
  • On Sticky Prices: Academic Theories Meet the Real World
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Monetary Policy Volume Author/Editor: N. Gregory Mankiw, ed. Volume Publisher: The University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-50308-9 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/greg94-1 Conference Date: January 21-24, 1993 Publication Date: January 1994 Chapter Title: On Sticky Prices: Academic Theories Meet the Real World Chapter Author: Alan S. Blinder Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c8331 Chapter pages in book: (p. 117 - 154) 4 On Sticky Prices: Academic Theories Meet the Real World Alan S. Blinder Any theory of how nominal money affects the real economy must face up to the following conundrum: Demand or supply functions derived-whether precisely or heuristically-from basic micro principles have money, M,as an argument only in ratio to the general price level. Hence, if monetary policy is to have real effects, there must be some reason why changes in M are not followed promptly by equiproportionate changes in I.! This is the sense in which some kind of “price stickiness” is essential to virtually any story of how monetary policy works.’ Keynes (1936) offered one of the first intellectually coherent (or was it?) explanations for price stickiness by positing that money wages are sticky, and perhaps even rigid-at least in the downward direction. In that case, what Keynes called “the money supply in wage units,” M/W, moves in the same direction as nominal money, thereby stimulating the economy. In the basic Keynesian model,2 prices are not sticky relative to wages.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    WP 2020-12 December 2020 Working Paper Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853-7801 USA Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, and Brody Viney It is the Policy of Cornell University actively to support equality of educational and employment opportunity. No person shall be denied admission to any educational program or activity or be denied employmen t on the basis of any legally prohibited discrimination involving, but not limited to, such factors as race, color, creed, religion, national or ethnic origin, sex, age or handicap. The University is committed to the maintenance of affirmative action prog rams which will assure the continuation of such equality of opportunity. 2 Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, Brody Viney ThisThis version: versio Augustn: Aug 6,us 2020t 6, 20201 Abstract This paper considers and assesses the concept of social externalities through human interdependence, in relation to the economic analysis of externalities in the tradition of Pigou and Arrow, including the analysis of the commons. It argues that there are limits to economic analysis. Our proposal is to enlarge the perspective and start thinking about a broader framework in which any pattern of influence of an agent or a group of agents over a third party, which is not mediated by any economic, social, or psychological mechanism guaranteeing the alignment of the marginal net private benefit with marginal net social benefit, can be attached the “externality” label and be scrutinized for the likely negative consequences that result from the divergence .These consequences may be significant given the many interactions between the social and economic realms, and the scope for spillovers and feedback loops to emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • The Pitfalls of External Dependence: Greece, 1829-2015
    BPEA Conference Draft, September 10-11, 2015 The pitfalls of external dependence: Greece, 1829-2015 Carmen M. Reinhart, Harvard University and NBER Christoph Trebesch, University of Munich and CESifo DO NOT DISTRIBUTE – EMBARGOED UNTIL 1:00 PM EST ON 9/10/2015 This draft: September 5, 2015 The Pitfalls of External Dependence: Greece, 1829-2015 Carmen M. Reinhart (Harvard University and NBER) Christoph Trebesch (University of Munich and CESifo) Abstract Two centuries of Greek debt crises highlight the pitfalls of relying on external financing. Since its independence in 1829, the Greek government has defaulted four times on its external creditors, and it was bailed out in each crisis. We show that cycles of external crises and dependence are a perennial theme of Greek modern history – with repeating patterns: prior to the default, there is a period of heavy borrowing from foreign private creditors. As repayment difficulties arise, foreign governments step in, help to repay the private creditors, and demand budget cuts and adjustment programs as a condition for the official bailout loans. Political interference from abroad mounts and a prolonged episode of debt overhang and financial autarky follows. At present, there is considerable evidence to suggest that a substantial haircut on external debt is needed to restore the economic viability of the country. Even with that, a policy priority for Greece is to reorient, to the extent possible, towards domestic sources of funding. *We wish to thank the Josefin Meyer, Michael Papaioannou, Vincent Reinhart, David Romer, and Julian Schumacher for helpful comments and Jochen Andritzky and Stellios Makrydakis for sharing the data from their studies, which we cite here.
    [Show full text]
  • Friedman and Schwartz's a Monetary History of the United States 1867
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NOT JUST THE GREAT CONTRACTION: FRIEDMAN AND SCHWARTZ’S A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES 1867 TO 1960 Michael D. Bordo Hugh Rockoff Working Paper 18828 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18828 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2013 Paper prepared for the Session: “The Fiftieth Anniversary of Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States”, American Economic Association Annual Meetings, San Diego, CA, January 6 2013. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2013 by Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Not Just the Great Contraction: Friedman and Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff NBER Working Paper No. 18828 February 2013 JEL No. B22,N1 ABSTRACT A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 published in 1963 was written as part of an extensive NBER research project on Money and Business Cycles started in the 1950s. The project resulted in three more books and many important articles. A Monetary History was designed to provide historical evidence for the modern quantity theory of money.
    [Show full text]
  • How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis?
    ® Economic Information Newsletter Liber8 Brought to You by the Research Library of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis November 2009 How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis? “Would financial markets and the economy have been better off if the Fed pursued a policy of quantitative easing sooner?” —Daniel L. Thornton, Vice President and Economic Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Synopses The government and the Federal Reserve’s response to the current recession continues to be hotly de bated. Several questions arise: Was a $780 billion economic stimulus bill appropriate? Was the Troubled Asset Re lief Program (TARP) beneficial? Should the Fed have increased the money supply sooner? Should Lehman Brothers have been allowed to fail? Some answers to these questions lie in economic theory, and whether prudent decisions were made depends on whom you ask. This article examines three modern schools of economic thought and how each school would advise was the best way to respond to the most recent crisis. The New Keynesian Approach New Keynesian economics, the “new” version of the school based on the works of the early twentieth- century economist John Maynard Keynes, is founded on two major assumptions. First, people are forward looking; that is, they use available information today (interest rates, stock prices, gas prices, and so on) to form expectations about the future. Second, prices and wages are “sticky,” meaning they adjust gradually. One example of “stickiness” is a union-negotiated contract, which is fixed for a definite period of time. Menus are also an example of price stickiness: The cost associated with reprinting menus causes a restaurant owner to be reluctant about replacing them.
    [Show full text]
  • Thoughts on Fiscal and Monetary Policy Since the Onset of the Global Financial Crisis
    The Great Moderation and the Great Confusion: thoughts on fiscal and monetary policy since the onset of the Global Financial Crisis “The central problem of depression-prevention [has] been solved for all practical purposes” Robert Lucas, incoming address to the American Economic Association, 2003 “I’ve looked at life from both sides now From win and lose and still somehow It’s life’s illusions I recall I really don’t know life at all” Joni Mitchell Clouds (1967) “The Great Moderation” is a term used in 2002 by James Stock and Mark Watson and given wider currency by Ben Bernanke, amongst others. It was presumably chosen to contrast with the Great Depression of the 1930s and, perhaps, the great stagflation of the 1970s. It began in the mid-1980s and lasted until the onset of the Global Financial Crisis in 2007. Between 2002 and 2007 much was written about the Great Moderation in what became an orgy of self-congratulation, especially on the part of monetary economists. The Great Moderation was characterised by two related, and obviously beneficial, phenomena. The first was much reduced volatility in business cycles. The second was an initial downward trend in inflation, followed by a sustained period of relatively stable low inflation. It is reasonable to argue that this occurred despite the fact that both the American and world economies suffered a number of shocks while the Great Moderation was occurring. The most notable of these were the sharemarket crash of 1987 and the Asian financial crisis of 1997. Interestingly enough, Stock and Watson argue that luck did play a significant part, that in fact the shocks were weaker than in previous eras.
    [Show full text]
  • Redefining the Role of the State: Joseph Stiglitz on Building A
    Redefining the Role of the State Joseph Stiglitz on building a ‘post-Washington consensus’ An interview with introduction by Brian Snowdon ‘Economic ideas—knowledge about economics—have had a profound effect on the lives of billions of people, making it absolutely essential that we do our best to try and understand the scientific basis of our theories and evidence…In practice, however, there are often large differences in the understanding of or about economic issues. The purpose of economic science is to narrow these dif- ferences by subjecting the positions and beliefs to rigorous analysis, statistical tests, and vigorous debate’. (Joseph Stiglitz, 1998a) Introduction Joseph Stiglitz is a remarkably productive economist and is internation- ally recognised as one of the world’s leading thinkers. To date, in his 35- year career as a professional economist (1966–2001), Professor Stiglitz has published well over three hundred papers in academic journals, con- ference proceedings and edited volumes. He is also the author and edi- tor of numerous books. In 1966, having completed his PhD at MIT, he embarked on an academic career during which he has taught and con- ducted research at many of the world’s most prestigious universities including MIT, Yale, Oxford, Princeton and Stanford. In 1979 he was awarded the prestigious John Bates Clark Medal from the American Economic Association, an award given to the most distinguished economist under the age of forty. From 1993–97 Professor Stiglitz was a member of the US President’s Council of Economic Advisors, becoming Chair of the CEA in June 1995. From February 1997 until his Joseph Stiglitz is currently (since July 2001) Professor of Economics, Business and International Affairs at Columbia University, New York.
    [Show full text]