The CRR Market Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The CRR Market Model 7: The CRR Market Model Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney MATH3075/3975 Financial Mathematics Semester 2, 2016 7: The CRR Market Model Outline We will examine the following issues: 1 The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein Market Model 2 The CRR Call Option Pricing Formula 3 Call and Put Options of American Style 4 Dynamic Programming Approach to American Claims 5 Examples: American Call and Put Options 7: The CRR Market Model PART 1 THE COX-ROSS-RUBINSTEIN MARKET MODEL 7: The CRR Market Model Introduction The Cox-Ross-Rubinstein market model (CRR model) is an example of a multi-period market model of the stock price. At each point in time, the stock price is assumed to either go ‘up’ by a fixed factor u or go ‘down’ by a fixed factor d. Only three parameters are needed to specify the binomial asset pricing model: u > d > 0 and r > 1. − Note that we do not postulate that d < 1 < u. The real-world probability of an ‘up’ mouvement is assumed to be the same 0 < p < 1 for each period and is assumed to be independent of all previous stock price mouvements. 7: The CRR Market Model Bernoulli Processes Definition (Bernoulli Process) A process X = (Xt )1 t T on a probability space (Ω, , P) is called ≤ ≤ F the Bernoulli process with parameter 0 < p < 1 if the random variables X1, X2,..., XT are independent and have the following common probability distribution P(Xt = 1) = 1 P(Xt =0)= p. − Definition (Bernoulli Counting Process) The Bernoulli counting process N = (Nt )0 t T is defined by setting N = 0 and, for every t = 1,..., T and≤ ≤ω Ω, 0 ∈ Nt (ω) := X (ω)+ X (ω)+ + Xt (ω). 1 2 · · · The process N is a special case of an additive random walk. 7: The CRR Market Model Stock Price Definition (Stock Price) The stock price process in the CRR model is defined via an initial value S > 0 and, for 1 t T and all ω Ω, 0 ≤ ≤ ∈ Nt (ω) t Nt (ω) St (ω) := S0u d − . The underlying Bernoulli process X governs the ‘up’ and ‘down’ mouvements of the stock. The stock price moves up at time t if Xt (ω) = 1 and moves down if Xt (ω) = 0. The dynamics of the stock price can be seen as an example of a multiplicative random walk. The Bernoulli counting process N counts the up mouvements. Before and including time t, the stock price moves up Nt times and down t Nt times. − 7: The CRR Market Model Distribution of the Stock Price For each t = 1, 2,..., T , the random variable Nt has the binomial distribution with parameters p and t. Specifically, for every t = 1,..., T and k = 0,..., t we have that t k t k P(Nt = k)= p (1 p) − . k − Hence the probability distribution of the stock price St at time t is given by k t k t k t k P(St = S u d − )= p (1 p) − 0 k − for k = 0, 1,..., t. 7: The CRR Market Model Stock Price Lattice 0.8 S u4 0 0.6 ... S u3 0 0.4 S u2 S u3d 0 0 0.2 S u S u2d 0 0 0 ... S S ud S u2d2 0 0 0 −0.2 S d S ud2 0 0 −0.4 3 S d2 S ud 0 0 −0.6 ... S d3 0 −0.8 S d4 0 −1 Figure: Stock Price Lattice in the CRR Model 7: The CRR Market Model Risk-Neutral Probability Measure Proposition (7.1) Assume that d < 1+ r < u. Then a probability measure P on (Ω, T ) is a risk-neutral probability measure for the CRR model F e = (B, S) with parameters p, u, d, r and time horizon T if and onlyM if: 1 X1, X2, X3,..., XT are independent under the probability measure P, 2 P 0 < p :=e (Xt = 1) < 1 for all t = 1,..., T , 3 pu + (1 p)d = (1+ r), e −e where X is the Bernoulli process governing the stock price S. e e 7: The CRR Market Model Risk-Neutral Probability Measure Proposition (7.2) If d < 1+ r < u then the CRR market model = (B, S) is arbitrage-free and complete. M Since the CRR model is complete, the unique arbitrage price of any European contingent claim can be computed using the risk-neutral valuation formula E X πt (X )= Bt P t BT F e We will apply this formula to the call option on the stock. 7: The CRR Market Model PART 2 THE CRR CALL OPTION PRICING FORMULA 7: The CRR Market Model CRR Call Option Pricing Formula Proposition (7.3) The arbitrage price at time t = 0 of the European call option + CT = (ST K) in the binomial market model = (B, S) is given by the− CRR call pricing formula M T T T k T k K T k T k C = S pˆ (1 pˆ) − p (1 p) − 0 0 k − − (1 + r)T k − Xk=kˆ Xk=kˆ e e where 1+ r d pu p = − , pˆ = u d 1+ r − e and kˆ is the smalleste integer k such that u K k log > log T . d S0d 7: The CRR Market Model Proof of Proposition 7.3 Proof of Proposition 7.3. + The price at time t = 0 of the claim X = CT = (ST K) can be − computed using the risk-neutral valuation under P 1 e C = E (CT ) . 0 (1 + r)T P e In view of Proposition 7.1, we obtain T 1 T k T k k T k C = p (1 p) − max 0, S u d − K . 0 (1 + r)T k − 0 − Xk=0 e e We note that k k T k u K S0u d − K > 0 > T − ⇔ d S0d u K k log > log T ⇔ d S0d 7: The CRR Market Model Proof of Proposition 7.3 Proof of Proposition 7.3 (Continued). We define kˆ = kˆ(S0, T ) as the smallest integer k such that the last inequality is satisfied. If there are less than kˆ upward mouvements there is no chance that the option will expire worthless. Therefore, we obtain T 1 T k T k k T k C = p (1 p) − S u d − K 0 (1 + r)T k − 0 − Xk=kˆ T e e S0 T k T k k T k = p (1 p) − u d − (1 + r)T k − Xk=kˆ T e e K T k T k p (1 p) − − (1 + r)T k − Xk=kˆ e e 7: The CRR Market Model Proof of Proposition 7.3 Proof of Proposition 7.3 (Continued). Consequently, T k T k T pu (1 p)d − C = S − 0 0 k 1+ r 1+ r Xk=kˆ e e T K T k T k p (1 p) − − (1 + r)T k − Xk=kˆ e e and thus T T T k T k K T k T k C = S pˆ (1 pˆ) − p (1 p) − 0 0 k − − (1 + r)T k − Xk=kˆ Xk=kˆ e e where we denotep ˆ = pu . 1+e r 7: The CRR Market Model Martingale Approach (MATH3975) pu 1+r d Check that 0 < pˆ = 1+r < 1 whenever 0 < p = u −d < 1. e − P Let be the probability measure obtained bye setting p = p in Proposition 7.1. Then the process B is a martingale under P. b S b For t = 0, the price of the call satisfies b C = S P(D) KB(0, T ) P(D) 0 0 − b e where D = ω Ω : ST (ω) > K . { ∈ } Recall that 1 + Ct = Bt E B− (ST K) t P T − | F e Using the abstract Bayes formula, one can show that Ct = St P(D t ) KB(t, T ) P(D t ). | F − | F b e 7: The CRR Market Model Put-Call Parity It is possible to derive explicit pricing formula for the call option at any date t = 0, 1,..., T . Since CT PT = ST K, we see that the following put-call − − parity holds at any date t = 0, 1,..., T (T t) Ct Pt = St K(1 + r)− − = St KB(t, T ) − − − where (T t) B(t, T )=(1+ r)− − is the price at time t of zero-coupon bond maturing at T . Using Proposition 7.3 and the put-call parity, one can derive an explicit pricing formula for the European put option with + the payoff PT = (K ST ) . This is left as an exercise. − 7: The CRR Market Model PART 3 CALL AND PUT OPTIONS OF AMERICAN STYLE 7: The CRR Market Model American Options In contrast to a contingent claim of a European style, a claim of an American style can by exercised by its holder at any date before its expiration date T . Definition (American Call and Put Options) An American call (put) option is a contract which gives the holder the right to buy (sell) an asset at any time t T at strike price K. ≤ It the study of an American claim, we are concerned with the price process and the ‘optimal’ exercise policy by its holder. If the holder of an American option exercises it at τ [0, T ], ∈ τ is called the exercise time. 7: The CRR Market Model Stopping Times An admissible exercise time should belong to the class of stopping times.
Recommended publications
  • Up to EUR 3,500,000.00 7% Fixed Rate Bonds Due 6 April 2026 ISIN
    Up to EUR 3,500,000.00 7% Fixed Rate Bonds due 6 April 2026 ISIN IT0005440976 Terms and Conditions Executed by EPizza S.p.A. 4126-6190-7500.7 This Terms and Conditions are dated 6 April 2021. EPizza S.p.A., a company limited by shares incorporated in Italy as a società per azioni, whose registered office is at Piazza Castello n. 19, 20123 Milan, Italy, enrolled with the companies’ register of Milan-Monza-Brianza- Lodi under No. and fiscal code No. 08950850969, VAT No. 08950850969 (the “Issuer”). *** The issue of up to EUR 3,500,000.00 (three million and five hundred thousand /00) 7% (seven per cent.) fixed rate bonds due 6 April 2026 (the “Bonds”) was authorised by the Board of Directors of the Issuer, by exercising the powers conferred to it by the Articles (as defined below), through a resolution passed on 26 March 2021. The Bonds shall be issued and held subject to and with the benefit of the provisions of this Terms and Conditions. All such provisions shall be binding on the Issuer, the Bondholders (and their successors in title) and all Persons claiming through or under them and shall endure for the benefit of the Bondholders (and their successors in title). The Bondholders (and their successors in title) are deemed to have notice of all the provisions of this Terms and Conditions and the Articles. Copies of each of the Articles and this Terms and Conditions are available for inspection during normal business hours at the registered office for the time being of the Issuer being, as at the date of this Terms and Conditions, at Piazza Castello n.
    [Show full text]
  • Futures and Options Workbook
    EEXAMININGXAMINING FUTURES AND OPTIONS TABLE OF 130 Grain Exchange Building 400 South 4th Street Minneapolis, MN 55415 www.mgex.com [email protected] 800.827.4746 612.321.7101 Fax: 612.339.1155 Acknowledgements We express our appreciation to those who generously gave their time and effort in reviewing this publication. MGEX members and member firm personnel DePaul University Professor Jin Choi Southern Illinois University Associate Professor Dwight R. Sanders National Futures Association (Glossary of Terms) INTRODUCTION: THE POWER OF CHOICE 2 SECTION I: HISTORY History of MGEX 3 SECTION II: THE FUTURES MARKET Futures Contracts 4 The Participants 4 Exchange Services 5 TEST Sections I & II 6 Answers Sections I & II 7 SECTION III: HEDGING AND THE BASIS The Basis 8 Short Hedge Example 9 Long Hedge Example 9 TEST Section III 10 Answers Section III 12 SECTION IV: THE POWER OF OPTIONS Definitions 13 Options and Futures Comparison Diagram 14 Option Prices 15 Intrinsic Value 15 Time Value 15 Time Value Cap Diagram 15 Options Classifications 16 Options Exercise 16 F CONTENTS Deltas 16 Examples 16 TEST Section IV 18 Answers Section IV 20 SECTION V: OPTIONS STRATEGIES Option Use and Price 21 Hedging with Options 22 TEST Section V 23 Answers Section V 24 CONCLUSION 25 GLOSSARY 26 THE POWER OF CHOICE How do commercial buyers and sellers of volatile commodities protect themselves from the ever-changing and unpredictable nature of today’s business climate? They use a practice called hedging. This time-tested practice has become a stan- dard in many industries. Hedging can be defined as taking offsetting positions in related markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Seeking Income: Cash Flow Distribution Analysis of S&P 500
    RESEARCH Income CONTRIBUTORS Berlinda Liu Seeking Income: Cash Flow Director Global Research & Design Distribution Analysis of S&P [email protected] ® Ryan Poirier, FRM 500 Buy-Write Strategies Senior Analyst Global Research & Design EXECUTIVE SUMMARY [email protected] In recent years, income-seeking market participants have shown increased interest in buy-write strategies that exchange upside potential for upfront option premium. Our empirical study investigated popular buy-write benchmarks, as well as other alternative strategies with varied strike selection, option maturity, and underlying equity instruments, and made the following observations in terms of distribution capabilities. Although the CBOE S&P 500 BuyWrite Index (BXM), the leading buy-write benchmark, writes at-the-money (ATM) monthly options, a market participant may be better off selling out-of-the-money (OTM) options and allowing the equity portfolio to grow. Equity growth serves as another source of distribution if the option premium does not meet the distribution target, and it prevents the equity portfolio from being liquidated too quickly due to cash settlement of the expiring options. Given a predetermined distribution goal, a market participant may consider an option based on its premium rather than its moneyness. This alternative approach tends to generate a more steady income stream, thus reducing trading cost. However, just as with the traditional approach that chooses options by moneyness, a high target premium may suffocate equity growth and result in either less income or quick equity depletion. Compared with monthly standard options, selling quarterly options may reduce the loss from the cash settlement of expiring calls, while selling weekly options could incur more loss.
    [Show full text]
  • The Promise and Peril of Real Options
    1 The Promise and Peril of Real Options Aswath Damodaran Stern School of Business 44 West Fourth Street New York, NY 10012 [email protected] 2 Abstract In recent years, practitioners and academics have made the argument that traditional discounted cash flow models do a poor job of capturing the value of the options embedded in many corporate actions. They have noted that these options need to be not only considered explicitly and valued, but also that the value of these options can be substantial. In fact, many investments and acquisitions that would not be justifiable otherwise will be value enhancing, if the options embedded in them are considered. In this paper, we examine the merits of this argument. While it is certainly true that there are options embedded in many actions, we consider the conditions that have to be met for these options to have value. We also develop a series of applied examples, where we attempt to value these options and consider the effect on investment, financing and valuation decisions. 3 In finance, the discounted cash flow model operates as the basic framework for most analysis. In investment analysis, for instance, the conventional view is that the net present value of a project is the measure of the value that it will add to the firm taking it. Thus, investing in a positive (negative) net present value project will increase (decrease) value. In capital structure decisions, a financing mix that minimizes the cost of capital, without impairing operating cash flows, increases firm value and is therefore viewed as the optimal mix.
    [Show full text]
  • Show Me the Money: Option Moneyness Concentration and Future Stock Returns Kelley Bergsma Assistant Professor of Finance Ohio Un
    Show Me the Money: Option Moneyness Concentration and Future Stock Returns Kelley Bergsma Assistant Professor of Finance Ohio University Vivien Csapi Assistant Professor of Finance University of Pecs Dean Diavatopoulos* Assistant Professor of Finance Seattle University Andy Fodor Professor of Finance Ohio University Keywords: option moneyness, implied volatility, open interest, stock returns JEL Classifications: G11, G12, G13 *Communications Author Address: Albers School of Business and Economics Department of Finance 901 12th Avenue Seattle, WA 98122 Phone: 206-265-1929 Email: [email protected] Show Me the Money: Option Moneyness Concentration and Future Stock Returns Abstract Informed traders often use options that are not in-the-money because these options offer higher potential gains for a smaller upfront cost. Since leverage is monotonically related to option moneyness (K/S), it follows that a higher concentration of trading in options of certain moneyness levels indicates more informed trading. Using a measure of stock-level dollar volume weighted average moneyness (AveMoney), we find that stock returns increase with AveMoney, suggesting more trading activity in options with higher leverage is a signal for future stock returns. The economic impact of AveMoney is strongest among stocks with high implied volatility, which reflects greater investor uncertainty and thus higher potential rewards for informed option traders. AveMoney also has greater predictive power as open interest increases. Our results hold at the portfolio level as well as cross-sectionally after controlling for liquidity and risk. When AveMoney is calculated with calls, a portfolio long high AveMoney stocks and short low AveMoney stocks yields a Fama-French five-factor alpha of 12% per year for all stocks and 33% per year using stocks with high implied volatility.
    [Show full text]
  • Derivative Securities
    2. DERIVATIVE SECURITIES Objectives: After reading this chapter, you will 1. Understand the reason for trading options. 2. Know the basic terminology of options. 2.1 Derivative Securities A derivative security is a financial instrument whose value depends upon the value of another asset. The main types of derivatives are futures, forwards, options, and swaps. An example of a derivative security is a convertible bond. Such a bond, at the discretion of the bondholder, may be converted into a fixed number of shares of the stock of the issuing corporation. The value of a convertible bond depends upon the value of the underlying stock, and thus, it is a derivative security. An investor would like to buy such a bond because he can make money if the stock market rises. The stock price, and hence the bond value, will rise. If the stock market falls, he can still make money by earning interest on the convertible bond. Another derivative security is a forward contract. Suppose you have decided to buy an ounce of gold for investment purposes. The price of gold for immediate delivery is, say, $345 an ounce. You would like to hold this gold for a year and then sell it at the prevailing rates. One possibility is to pay $345 to a seller and get immediate physical possession of the gold, hold it for a year, and then sell it. If the price of gold a year from now is $370 an ounce, you have clearly made a profit of $25. That is not the only way to invest in gold.
    [Show full text]
  • Deep Optimal Stopping
    Journal of Machine Learning Research 20 (2019) 1-25 Submitted 4/18; Revised 1/19; Published 4/19 Deep Optimal Stopping Sebastian Becker [email protected] Zenai AG, 8045 Zurich, Switzerland Patrick Cheridito [email protected] RiskLab, Department of Mathematics ETH Zurich, 8092 Zurich, Switzerland Arnulf Jentzen [email protected] SAM, Department of Mathematics ETH Zurich, 8092 Zurich, Switzerland Editor: Jon McAuliffe Abstract In this paper we develop a deep learning method for optimal stopping problems which directly learns the optimal stopping rule from Monte Carlo samples. As such, it is broadly applicable in situations where the underlying randomness can efficiently be simulated. We test the approach on three problems: the pricing of a Bermudan max-call option, the pricing of a callable multi barrier reverse convertible and the problem of optimally stopping a fractional Brownian motion. In all three cases it produces very accurate results in high- dimensional situations with short computing times. Keywords: optimal stopping, deep learning, Bermudan option, callable multi barrier reverse convertible, fractional Brownian motion 1. Introduction N We consider optimal stopping problems of the form supτ E g(τ; Xτ ), where X = (Xn)n=0 d is an R -valued discrete-time Markov process and the supremum is over all stopping times τ based on observations of X. Formally, this just covers situations where the stopping decision can only be made at finitely many times. But practically all relevant continuous- time stopping problems can be approximated with time-discretized versions. The Markov assumption means no loss of generality. We make it because it simplifies the presentation and many important problems already are in Markovian form.
    [Show full text]
  • Options Glossary of Terms
    OPTIONS GLOSSARY OF TERMS Alpha Often considered to represent the value that a portfolio manager adds to or subtracts from a fund's return. A positive alpha of 1.0 means the fund has outperformed its benchmark index by 1%. Correspondingly, a similar negative alpha would indicate an underperformance of 1%. Alpha Indexes Each Alpha Index measures the performance of a single name “Target” (e.g. AAPL) versus a “Benchmark (e.g. SPY). The relative daily total return performance is calculated daily by comparing price returns and dividends to the previous trading day. The Alpha Indexes were set at 100.00 as of January 1, 2010. The Alpha Indexes were created by NASDAQ OMX in conjunction with Jacob S. Sagi, Financial Markets Research Center Associate Professor of Finance, Owen School of Management, Vanderbilt University and Robert E. Whaley, Valere Blair Potter Professor of Management and Co-Director of the FMRC, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University. American- Style Option An option contract that may be exercised at any time between the date of purchase and the expiration date. At-the-Money An option is at-the-money if the strike price of the option is equal to the market price of the underlying index. Benchmark Component The second component identified in an Alpha Index. Call An option contract that gives the holder the right to buy the underlying index at a specified price for a certain fixed period of time. Class of Options Option contracts of the same type (call or put) and style (American or European) that cover the same underlying index.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 21 . Options
    Chapter 21 : Options-1 CHAPTER 21 . OPTIONS Contents I. INTRODUCTION · BASIC TERMS II. VALUATION OF OPTIONS A. Minimum Values of Options B. Maximum Values of Options C. Determinants of Call Value D. Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model (1973, BSOPM) E. Put-Call Parity III. EXERCISE FOR PAYOFF DIAGRAM IV. ASSIGNED PROBLEMS FROM THE TEXTBOOK V. SELF-EXERCISE PROBLEMS I. INTRODUCTION · BASIC TERMS 1. Option : right to buy (or sell) an asset at a fixed price on or before a given date Right ® buyer of option has no obligation, seller of option is obligated Call ® right to buy Put ® right to sell Note: Option may be written on any type of asset => most common is stock 2. Exercising the option - buying or selling asset by using option 3. Strike (or exercise) price - price at which asset may be bought or sold 4. Expiration date - last date on which option may be exercised 5. European option - may be exercised only at expiration date 6. American option - may be exercised on or before expiration date 7. In-the-money - positive cash flow if exercised ® call [put] =? 8. Out-of-the-money - negative cash flow if exercised ® call [put] = ? Chapter 21 : Options-2 9. At-the-money - zero cash flow if exercised ® call [put] = ? Chapter 21 : Options-3 II. VALUATION OF OPTIONS A. Minimum Values of Options 1. Minimum Value of Call A call option is an instrument with limited liability. If the call holder sees that it is advantageous to exercise it, the call will be exercised. If exercising it will decrease the call holder's wealth, the holder will not exercise it.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Stopping Time and Its Applications to Economic Models
    OPTIMAL STOPPING TIME AND ITS APPLICATIONS TO ECONOMIC MODELS SIVAKORN SANGUANMOO Abstract. This paper gives an introduction to an optimal stopping problem by using the idea of an It^odiffusion. We then prove the existence and unique- ness theorems for optimal stopping, which will help us to explicitly solve opti- mal stopping problems. We then apply our optimal stopping theorems to the economic model of stock prices introduced by Samuelson [5] and the economic model of capital goods. Both economic models show that those related agents are risk-loving. Contents 1. Introduction 1 2. Preliminaries: It^odiffusion and boundary value problems 2 2.1. It^odiffusions and their properties 2 2.2. Harmonic function and the stochastic Dirichlet problem 4 3. Existence and uniqueness theorems for optimal stopping 5 4. Applications to an economic model: Stock prices 11 5. Applications to an economic model: Capital goods 14 Acknowledgments 18 References 19 1. Introduction Since there are several outside factors in the real world, many variables in classi- cal economic models are considered as stochastic processes. For example, the prices of stocks and oil do not just increase due to inflation over time but also fluctuate due to unpredictable situations. Optimal stopping problems are questions that ask when to stop stochastic pro- cesses in order to maximize utility. For example, when should one sell an asset in order to maximize his profit? When should one stop searching for the keyword to obtain the best result? Therefore, many recent economic models often include op- timal stopping problems. For example, by using optimal stopping, Choi and Smith [2] explored the effectiveness of the search engine, and Albrecht, Anderson, and Vroman [1] discovered how the search cost affects the search for job candidates.
    [Show full text]
  • The Duration of Optimal Stopping Problems
    arXiv: 1810.11557 THE DURATION OF OPTIMAL STOPPING PROBLEMS By Simon Demers Optimal stopping problems give rise to random distributions de- scribing how many applicants the decision-maker will sample or in- terview before choosing one, a quantity sometimes referred to as the search time or process duration. This research note surveys several variants of optimal stopping problems, extends earlier results in var- ious directions, and shows how many interviews are expected to be conducted in various settings. The focus is on problems that require a decision-maker to choose a candidate from a pool of sequential appli- cants with no recall, in the vein of previously studied Cayley-Moser, Secretary and Sultan's Dowry problems. 1. Introduction. Although optimal stopping problems have been stud- ied and refined extensively over time (Gilbert and Mosteller, 1966; Freeman, 1983; Ferguson, 1989a), relatively little is currently known about the statis- tical properties of the random distributions they give rise to. For example, it is not obvious how the expected number of observations (\applicants") to be considered (\interviewed") before one is ultimately chosen (\hired") will vary when the decision-maker (\employer") can observe the actual pay- off values (\talent") or when the horizon (\applicant pool") grows. This is unfortunate because it might be useful in some practical settings to antici- pate, for example, how many interviews the decision-maker should plausibly schedule or prepare for. This is what this research note attempts to elucidate. The focus is on the problem of choosing a candidate from a pool of ap- plicants with no recall and uniformly distributed talent.
    [Show full text]
  • Empirical Properties of Straddle Returns
    EDHEC RISK AND ASSET MANAGEMENT RESEARCH CENTRE 393-400 promenade des Anglais 06202 Nice Cedex 3 Tel.: +33 (0)4 93 18 32 53 E-mail: [email protected] Web: www.edhec-risk.com Empirical Properties of Straddle Returns December 2008 Felix Goltz Head of applied research, EDHEC Risk and Asset Management Research Centre Wan Ni Lai IAE, University of Aix Marseille III Abstract Recent studies find that a position in at-the-money (ATM) straddles consistently yields losses. This is interpreted as evidence for the non-redundancy of options and as a risk premium for volatility risk. This paper analyses this risk premium in more detail by i) assessing the statistical properties of ATM straddle returns, ii) linking these returns to exogenous factors and iii) analysing the role of straddles in a portfolio context. Our findings show that ATM straddle returns seem to follow a random walk and only a small percentage of their variation can be explained by exogenous factors. In addition, when we include the straddle in a portfolio of the underlying asset and a risk-free asset, the resulting optimal portfolio attributes substantial weight to the straddle position. However, the certainty equivalent gains with respect to the presence of a straddle in a portfolio are small and probably do not compensate for transaction costs. We also find that a high rebalancing frequency is crucial for generating significant negative returns and portfolio benefits. Therefore, from an investor's perspective, straddle trading does not seem to be an attractive way to capture the volatility risk premium. JEL Classification: G11 - Portfolio Choice; Investment Decisions, G12 - Asset Pricing, G13 - Contingent Pricing EDHEC is one of the top five business schools in France.
    [Show full text]