The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Divi- Sion I, 74 YALE L.J

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Divi- Sion I, 74 YALE L.J THE YALE LAW JOURNAL VOLUME 75 JANUARY 1966 No. 3 THE RULEOF REASON AND THE PER SE CONCEPT: PRICEFIXING AND MARKETDIVISION* ROBERTH. BORKt TABLE OF CONTENTS THE RULE OF REASON: ANCILLARY RESTRAINTS AND THE PER SE RULE 377 The Present Confusion Concerning the Per Se Rule ..... ....... 378 The Respective Functions of the Per Se Rule and the Doctrine of Ancillary Restraints .......... ............................ 380 The Propriety of a Per Se Rule ........ ........................ 384 The Rule of Reason In the Trial Process ...... ................ 387 RESTRICTION OF OUTPUT: HORIZONTAL AND VERTICAL RESTRAINTS .... 391 Horizontal Market Division and Price Fixing ..... .............. 391 Vertical Market Division and Price Fixing ...... ............... 397 A Consideration of Some Objections to the Legality of Vertical Restraints .................. ............................ 405 The Dealer Cartel Objection ........ ........................ 405 The Manufacturer Cartel Objection ...... ................... 411 The Objection that Vertical Restraints Transfer Imperfect Market Structures . ............................................. 415 This is the second section of a three-part article. The first appeared in 74 YALEL.J. 775 (1965). The author wishes to acknowledge his great indebtedness to Professor Ward S. Bowman for many invaluable conversations on the topics discussed here and for his criti- cisms of a draft of this section. It should also be mentioned that the second and third sections of the article constitute a substantial expansion on and partial modification of views previously expressed in Bork, Ancillary Restraints and the Sherman Act, 15 A.B.A. SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW 211 (1959). t Professor of Law, Yale University. 374 THE YALE LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 75:373 The Problem of Price Discrimination ...... .................. 416 The Problem of Distinguishing Between Horizontal and Vertical Restraints ............... ............................... 424 CREATION OF EFFICIENCY: MARKET DIVISION AND PRICE FIXING ...... 429 Market-Division Agreements ........ .......................... 430 1. Local Sales Effort: The Free-Ride Problem ..... ........... 430 2. Local Sales Effort: The Size-of-the-Market Problem .... .... 438 3. Exchanges of Information ....... ....................... 439 4. Post-Sale Service ........................................ 446 5. Effectiveness of a Service or Facility Whose Cost Is Shared .... 449 6. Minimizing Costs and Customer Irritation Due to Overlapping Distributive Efforts ............. ...................... 451 Price-Fixing Agreements ...................................... 453 1. Local Sales Effort: The Free-Ride Problem ..... ........... 453 2. Local Sales Effort: The Uniform Product ...... ............ 454 3. Reinforcing a Market-Division System ...... .............. 456 4. Providing the Means of Transferring Information ..... ..... 457 5. Economies of Scale In Advertising ....... ................. 460 6. Protection Against Fraud by a Joint Venturer ..... ......... 461 7. Breaking Down Cartels and Controlling Local Monopolies ... 464 ALTERNATIVES AND OBJECTIONS TO THE DOCTRINE OF ANCILLARY RE- STRAINTS .................................................. 465 The Alternative Suggestions .............. .................... 465 The Inadequacy of Exclusive Franchises and Profit Pass-Over Sys- tems . .............................................. 466 The Fallacy of Area-of-Primary-Responsibility Clauses ..... ..... 467 The Objections: Three False Issues ......... ................... 469 The Dual Distribution Objection ......... ................... 470 Interbrand Versus Intrabrand Competition ...... ............. 472 Consumer Choice Between Lower Prices and Alternative Induce- ments ................................................ 473 SUMMARY . ............................................... 473 1966] THE RULE OF REASON 375 II THE first section of this article' argued that the uncertainty and inconsistency which patently afflict the law concerning price fixing and market division are attributable to the twofold failure of Sherman Act courts to be clear about the ultimate values the law implements and to develop a realistic analysis of the economic phenomena with which the law is required to deal. The main tradition of the Sherman Act's rule of reason-established by Justice Peckham, Judge Taft, and Chief Justice White in 1911- necessarily rests, whether phrased in such terms or not, upon the premise that the law's exclusive concern is with the maximization of wealth or consumer want satisfaction. Though this premise is not the only one upon which social legislation may be based, it is implicit- and sometimes explicit-in the key decisions which established the main tradition of the rule of reason, and it is, moreover, the only premise capable of producing rational decisional law under the Sher- man Act as now written. Acceptance of consumer want satisfaction as the law's ultimate value requires the courts to employ as their primary criterion the impact of any agreement upon output, and thus to determine whether the net effect of the agreement is to create efficiency, and thereby increase output or, alternatively, to restrict output.2 This common acceptance of the wealth-maximization premise and its inherent standards of judgment explains why the interpreta- tions given the Sherman Act by Peckham, Taft and White, despite their widely differing phrasings, were so similar in result, and why each 1. Bork, The Rule of Reason and the Per Se Concept: Price Fixing and Market Divi- sion I, 74 YALE L.J. 775 (1965). 2. Peckham, Taft, and White all displayed concern that the law not destroy efficient forms of combination but that it strike down combinations whose sole effect was the elim- ination of competition. Id. at 783-805, 829-32. White most explicitly defined the evil to be avoided as restriction of output because his version of the common law, which he incor- porated into the Act, viewed the evils of monopoly as: (1) the power to fix price; (2) the power to limit production; and (3) the danger of deterioration in quality. Id. at 802. These evils are each reducible to restriction of output. The second-limitation of produc- tion-is obviously that. The first-the power to fix prices-can be wielded only by re- stricting output. The third-deterioration in quality-is merely a restriction of output accomplished by putting less into each item produced rather than making fewer items. The net effect of the two opposing tendencies-efficiency and restriction of output- determines whether the questioned agreement is efficient in the larger sense of allocating resources to maximize consumer want satisfaction. In order to avoid confusion, the nar- rower meaning of efficiency will be used throughout this article. The broader meaning will be indicated by such phrases as consumer want satisfaction, wealth maximization, etc. 376 THE YALE LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 75:373 assigned a prominent place within the rule of reason to a category of agreements illegal per se. The primary deviant tradition of the rule of reason-originally espoused by Justice White in 1897 and in 1918 by Justice Brandeis- rejects consumer welfare as the sole value of the law and admits com- peting considerations, most notably, perhaps, concern for small pro- ducers. The criteria required by the simultaneous use of wholly inconsistent values are necessarily either arbitrary or indefinable. Probably because this deviant strain has never become dominant, the criteria of the Brandeis tradition have in fact remained rather vague. They seem reducible, however, to the idea, early rejected by the judges of the main tradition, that a cartel should be judged by the "reason- ableness" of the price it fixes. White's 1897 Trans-Missouri dissent is thus to be equated with Brandeis' reading of the Act in the 1918 Chi- cago Board of Trade opinion. The introduction of values incompatible with consumer welfare, values that could, in fact, be furthered by cartel agreements at the expense of consumers, was the reason that neither White (in 1897) nor Brandeis (in 1918) gave a prominent, or perhaps any, role to the per se concept. The main tradition, with its insistence upon efficiency and re- striction of output as the standards of the Sherman Act, is, therefore, entitled to be preferred not merely as a matter of precedent but also because of its exclusive ability to achieve those attributes of rationality, efficacy, tolerable certainty, and the proper demarcation of the respec- tive functions of legislature and judiciary which are characteristics of good law.3 Though a proper choice of values is necessary to good law it is not sufficient. The Sherman Act, which deals with price fixing and market division in widely varying business contexts, requires a coherent analytical structure to translate values into conclusions. The Act, how- ever, has not evolved doctrine adequate to cope with this diversity of phenomena. Too often the law deals with particular forms of price fix- ing and market division as isolated and unique topics, neglecting to locate each within a rational conception of the whole. Perhaps just as often the law commits the opposite error of failing to make distinctions corresponding to economic differences, and applies broad formulas to situations in which they are wholly inappropriate. This second section of a three-part article attempts to provide a general theory capable of 3. 74 YALEL.J. 775, at 829-47 and particularly at 831-32, 840-47. 1966] THE RULE OF REASON 377 making
Recommended publications
  • Antitrust Enforcement and the Consumer
    Many consumers have never heard of antitrust laws, but when these laws are effectively and responsibly enforced, they can save consumers millions and even billions of dollars a year in illegal overcharges. Most States have antitrust laws, and so does the Federal Government. Essentially, these laws prohibit business practices that unreasonably deprive consumers of the benefits of competition, U.S. Department of Justice resulting in higher prices for inferior Washington, DC 20530 products and services. This pamphlet was prepared to alert consumers to the existence and importance of antitrust laws and to explain what you can do for antitrust enforcement and for yourself. 1. What Do the Antitrust Laws Do for the Consumer? Antitrust Antitrust laws protect competition. Free and open competition benefits consumers Enforcement by ensuring lower prices and new and better products. In a freely competitive and the market, each competing business generally Consumer will try to attract consumers by cutting its prices and increasing the quality of its products or services. Competition and the profit opportunities it brings also stimulate businesses to find new, innovative, and more efficient methods of production. Consumers benefit from competition through lower prices and better products and services. Companies that fail to understand or react to consumer needs may soon find themselves losing out in the competitive battle. When competitors agree to fix prices, rig bids, or allocate (divide up) customers, consumers lose the benefits of competition. The prices that result when competitors agree in these ways are artificially high; such prices do not accurately reflect cost and therefore distort the allocation of society’s resources.
    [Show full text]
  • Making the Most out of United States Antitrust Limitations on International Licensing Practicest
    JAMES H. WALLACE, JR.* Overlooked Opportunities-Making the Most Out of United States Antitrust Limitations on International Licensing Practicest The title of this article, "Overlooked Opportunities-Making the Most Out of United States Antitrust Limitations on International Licensing Practices," may seem puzzling if not disturbing to the reader. Unfortunately, all too often parties to license negotiations view the United States antitrust laws as the enemy-some- thing to be evaded, ignored, or complained about. As a result, companies sometimes take action which fails to maximize licensing profits. Moreover, in addition to such commercial losses, companies often find that their inattention to antitrust details can result in massive litigation expenses and liabilities. It may therefore be helpful to suggest a few ways to maximize licensing opportunities by properly recognizing United States antitrust limitations, rather than ignoring such legal constraints. But first, a brief review of some basic principles is in order. I. Some Basic Principles A. Distance Does Not Necessarily Guarantee Immunity from United States Antitrust Laws-Capture of the "Flying Dutchman" It is obvious and well known to United States companies that they are fully accountable under the United States antitrust laws for their licensing practices in the United States courts. And, although most experienced companies now recognize that just being foreign does not immunize them from United States antitrust actions, few really understand how easy it is for them to become defendants in the United States courts. The United States antitrust laws frequently apply to technology agreements *Partner. law tirm of Kirkland, Ellis & Rowe, Washington. D.C. tThis article is based upon a paper delivered by the author at the World Trade Institute, World Trade Center.
    [Show full text]
  • Hearing on Oligopoly Markets, Note by the United States Submitted To
    Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 12-Jun-2015 ___________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________ English - Or. English DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Unclassified DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 HEARING ON OLIGOPOLY MARKETS -- Note by the United States -- 16-18 June 2015 This document reproduces a written contribution from the United States submitted for Item 5 of the 123rd meeting of the OECD Competition Committee on 16-18 June 2015. More documents related to this discussion can be found at www.oecd.org/daf/competition/oligopoly-markets.htm. English English JT03378438 Complete document available on OLIS in its original format - This document and any map included herein are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of English Or. international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. DAF/COMP/WD(2015)45 UNITED STATES 1. Following on our submissions to previous OECD roundtables on oligopolies, notably the 1999 submission of the U.S. Department of Justice and the U.S. Federal Trade Commission on Oligopoly (describing the theoretical and economic underpinnings of U.S. enforcement policy with regard to oligopolistic behavior),1 and the 2007 U.S. submission on facilitating practices in oligopolies,2 this submission focuses on certain approaches taken by the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) and the U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Division (“DOJ”) (together, “the Agencies”) to prevent the accumulation of unwarranted market power and address oligopoly issues. 2. Pursuant to U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance in China – an Increasingly Economic Question
    Resale Price Maintenance in China – an increasingly economic question Three recent decisions in China suggest that Resale Specifically, the Court was clear that since RPM was Price Maintenance cases will not be decided solely on a defined in the law as a “monopoly agreement”, it must be legal consideration but will also turn on the economic expected to have the impact of eliminating or restricting context of the agreements in question. competition in order to be found illegal. To determine whether the agreement had the impact of eliminating or Resale Price Maintenance (RPM) is a contractual restricting competition, the Court proposed four constituent commitment imposed by a supplier on its distributors not to economic questions: sell its product for less (or more) than a given price. It is very 1. Is competition in the relevant market “sufficient”? common in distribution contracts throughout the world, 2. Does the defendant have a “very strong” market especially in China because of the control that RPM position? provides over resale quality and the distribution chain. 3. What was the motive behind the RPM agreements? RPM is a particularly contentious area of competition law 4. What was the competitive effect of the RPM? since RPM clauses can be both beneficial and harmful to competition depending on the context in which they are implemented. For example, RPM may facilitate unlawful Specifically, the Court suggested that if competition in the collusion between suppliers by allowing them to control and market was sufficient then it would not have found the RPM monitor the final retail price. RPM may also be forced on agreement illegal.
    [Show full text]
  • The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2000 The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H. Lande University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Howard P. Marvel Ohio State University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules, 2000 Wis. L. Rev. 941 (2000) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES THE THREE TYPES OF COLLUSION: FIXING PRICES, RIVALS, AND RULES ROBERTH. LANDE * & HOWARDP. MARVEL** Antitrust law has long held collusion to be paramount among the offenses that it is charged with prohibiting. The reason for this prohibition is simple----collusion typically leads to monopoly-like outcomes, including monopoly profits that are shared by the colluding parties. Most collusion cases can be classified into two established general categories.) Classic, or "Type I" collusion involves collective action to raise price directly? Firms can also collude to disadvantage rivals in a manner that causes the rivals' output to diminish or causes their behavior to become chastened. This "Type 11" collusion in turn allows the colluding firms to raise prices.3 Many important collusion cases, however, do not fit into either of these categories.
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Trade Commission Volume Decision
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION DECISIONS Findings, Opinions and Orders IN THE MATTER OF RUSSELL STOVER CANDIES, INC. FINAL ORDER, OPINION, ETC. , IN REGARD TO ALLEGED VIOLATION OF SEC. 5 OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION ACT Docket 9140. Complaint, July 1980-Final Order, July , 1982 This order requires a Kansas City, Mo. manufacturer, seller and distributor of candy products to cease, among other things, entering into, maintaining, or enforcing any ageement, understanding or arrangement to fix resale prices for its products; suggesting resale prices, by any means, without clearly stating that they are merely suggested; and seeking information relating to recalcitrant retailers. The respondent is prohibited from terminating, sus pending or taking any other adverse action against retailers who fail to conform to company s suggested prices; and required to reinstate those retailers who had been terminated for non-conformance to designated prices. The order additionally requires respondent to pay for a survey to ascertain what percentage of its products is sold at manufacturer-designated prices, and to cease suggesting resale prices if that percentae exceeds 87. 4%. Appearances For the Commission: Eugene Kaplan, Jayma M. Meyer and Warren Josephson. For the respondent: Lawrence R. Brown and David Everson, Stinson, Mag Fizzell Kansas City, Mo. and Tom Franklin, in- house counsel, Kansas City, Mo. COMPLAINT Pursuant to the provisions of the Federal Trade Commission Act as amended, and by virtue of the authority vested in it by said Act the Federal Trade Commission, having reason to believe that Russell Stover Candies, Inc. , a corporation, hereinafter referred to as respondent, has violated the provisions of said Act, and it appearing to the Commission that a proceeding by it in respect thereof would be in the public interest, hereby issues its complaint stating its charges in that respect as follows: FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION DECISIONS Initial Decision 100 F.
    [Show full text]
  • The United States Has a Market Concentration Problem Reviewing Concentration Estimates in Antitrust Markets, 2000-Present
    THE UNITED STATES HAS A MARKET CONCENTRATION PROBLEM REVIEWING CONCENTRATION ESTIMATES IN ANTITRUST MARKETS, 2000-PRESENT ISSUE BRIEF BY ADIL ABDELA AND MARSHALL STEINBAUM1 | SEPTEMBER 2018 Since the 1970s, America’s antitrust policy regime has been weakening and market power has been on the rise. High market concentration—in which few firms compete in a given market—is one indicator of market power. From 1985 to 2017, the number of mergers completed annually rose from 2,308 to 15,361 (IMAA 2017). Recently, policymakers, academics, and journalists have questioned whether the ongoing merger wave, and lax antitrust enforcement more generally, is indeed contributing to rising concentration, and in turn, whether concentration really portends a market power crisis in the economy. In this issue brief, we review the estimates of market concentration that have been conducted in a number of industries since 2000 as part of merger retrospectives and other empirical investigations. The result of that survey is clear: market concentration in the U.S. economy is high, according to the thresholds adopted by the antitrust agencies themselves in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines. By way of background, recent studies of industry concentration conclude that it is both high and rising over time. For example, Grullon, Larkin, and Michaely conclude that concentration increased in 75% of industries from 1997 to 2012. In response to these and similar studies, the antitrust enforcement agencies recently declared that their findings are not relevant to the question of whether market concentration has increased because they study industrial sectors, not antitrust markets. Specifically, they wrote, “The U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • "Application of Part IV of the Trade Practices Act to Local Government"
    "Application of Part IV of the Trade Practices Act to Local Government" Michael Cosgrave Regional Director - Melbourne Application of National Competition Policy to Local Government Seminar 30 July 1996 Introduction As you are no doubt all aware, from 21 July 1996 the Trade Practices Act 1974 ("the Act") was further extended under National Competition Policy. All States except Western Australia have enacted legislation conforming with the Competition Policy Reform Act, thus extending the ambit of the Act to now include many previously exempt business activities of Australian Local Governments. The application of the Act is important for every one of you here today. A message that I want to impart to you today is that each local government is now going to be responsible for its the competition effects of its actions. The significance of the new coverage of the Act is that local governments now have to ensure that their legislation does not breach the Act and that its business organisations engage in fair trade practices. That said, the principles of the Act are nothing new for all local governments - many governments have been parties to contracts with corporations that are subject to the Act; furthermore, the provisions of the Act are basically common sense and basic fair trade principles. Claire Thomas this morning, and Professor Fels, the Chairman of the Commission, two months ago have discussed with you the position of Local Government under the NCP Reforms. Today I am going to go into more detail about Part IV of the Act, in particular, its application to Local Governments.
    [Show full text]
  • Criminal Sanctions for Cartel Behaviour
    CRIMINAL SANCTIONS FOR CARTEL BEHAVIOUR ANTHONY GRAY* I INTRODUCTION The Trade Practices Amendment (Cartel Conduct and Other Measures) Bill 2008 (Cth) controversially proposes the introduction of criminal sanctions for certain cartel behaviour. These measures were recommended by the Dawson Committee in its 2003 review, 1 and not surprisingly have the support of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC).2 In this article, I will introduce the proposed new rules, 3 before assessing whether cartel conduct should be criminalised, in terms of traditional conceptions of what behaviour should be considered to be criminal in nature, as well as the likely effectiveness of the new regime in terms of deterring cartel behaviour, and enforcing cartel provisions more generally. II OUTLINE OF PROPOSED NEW RULES Proposed new s 44ZZRF of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth) will make it an offence for an individual4 to: (a) make a contract or arrangement, or arrive at an understanding,5 with the intention of dishonestly6 obtaining a benefit,7 where * BBus (Acc), LLB (Hons), LLM (QUT), PhD (UNSW), Associate Professor in the School of Law, University of Southern Queensland. Thanks to an anonymous referee for helpful comments on an earlier draft. 1 Review of the Competition Provisions of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (2003) (Dawson Review) Trade Practices Act Review <http://tpareview.treasury.gov.au/content/home.asp> at 8 November 2008; R Steinwall, ‘The Dawson Committee Review of the Competition Provisions of the Trade Practices Act’ (2003) 11 Competition and Consumer Law Journal 87. 2 Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Submission to the Trade Practices Act Review (2002) Trade Practices Act Review <http://tpareview.treasury.gov.au/submissions.asp> at 8 November 2008.
    [Show full text]
  • Official Journal of the European Communities on the Definition Of
    9 . 12 . 97 [ EN ] Official Journal of the European Communities C 372/ 5 COMMISSION NOTICE on the definition of relevant market for the purposes of Community competition law (97/C 372/03 ) ( Text with EEA relevance ) I. INTRODUCTION 3 . It follows from point 2 that the concept of 'relevant market' is different from other definitions of market often used in other contexts . For instance , companies often use the term 'market' to refer to the area 1 . The purpose of this notice is to provide guidance as where it sells its products or to refer broadly to the to how the Commission applies the concept of industry or sector where it belongs . relevant product and geographic market in its ongoing enforcement of Community competition 4 . The definition of the relevant market in both its law, in particular the application of Council Regu­ product and its geographic dimensions often has a lation No 17 and (EEC ) No 4064/ 89 , their decisive influence on the assessment of a competition equivalents in other sectoral applications such as case . By rendering public the procedures which the transport, coal and steel , and agriculture , and the Commission follows when considering market defi­ relevant provisions of the EEA Agreement ('). nition and by indicating the criteria and evidence on Throughout this notice , references to Articles 85 and which it relies to reach a decision , the Commission 86 of the Treaty and to merger control are to be expects to increase the transparency of its policy and understood as referring to the equivalent provisions decision-making in the area of competition policy .
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust--Past and Present Milton Handler Columbia University
    Kentucky Law Journal Volume 51 | Issue 3 Article 1 1963 Antitrust--Past and Present Milton Handler Columbia University Follow this and additional works at: https://uknowledge.uky.edu/klj Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Right click to open a feedback form in a new tab to let us know how this document benefits you. Recommended Citation Handler, Milton (1963) "Antitrust--Past and Present," Kentucky Law Journal: Vol. 51 : Iss. 3 , Article 1. Available at: https://uknowledge.uky.edu/klj/vol51/iss3/1 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UKnowledge. It has been accepted for inclusion in Kentucky Law Journal by an authorized editor of UKnowledge. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Antitrust--Past and Present By MILTON HANDLER* Ashley, in his authoritative treatise on the Economic Organiza- tion of England,' distinguishes four pnncipal stages of economic development: (1) the family or household system in which the material needs of an agricultural society are satisfied by the produc- tion of goods in the farm or manor house; (2) the guild or handi- craft system in which professional craftsmen produce wares on a small scale in their own dwellings on a custom made basis for their consumer-customers; (3) the domestic system or house industry in which commercial middlemen act as intermediaries between the makers of goods in small domestic workshops and the ultimate users; and (4) the factory system in which production is organized on a large scale in spacious factories equipped with costly ma- chinery and distribution is controlled by the manufacturers who supply retail establishments either directly or through marketing middlemen.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Fixing and Repeated Games
    9781405176323_4_014.qxd 10/19/07 8:12 PM Page 323 14 Price Fixing and Repeated Games In February 2007, the European Union Competition Directorate imposed their largest-ever fines on companies found guilty of colluding to fix prices. Five elevator manufacturers were fined a total of a992 million (approximately $1.4 billion) for operating a cartel that con- trolled prices in Germany, Belgium, Luxembourg and the Netherlands. ThuysenKrupp received the heaviest fine, of more than a479 million since it was judged to be a “repeat offender” by the Commission. Otis was fined a225 million, Schindler a144 million, Kone a142 million, and Mitsubishi’s Dutch subsidiary a1.8 million.1 The elevator case came just one month after another case involving gas insulated switch- gear projects in which the Commission imposed fines totally a750 million on 11 companies for their parts in a price-fixing cartel. In this case, the largest fine of a396.5 million was imposed on Siemens, Germany. This case is particularly interesting because it was broken open largely as a result of the Commission’s leniency policy. Under that policy, the first firm in a conspiracy to confess and “fink” on its co-conspirators gets a much reduced penalty. In fact, the finking firm in the switch-gear case, ABB Switzerland, was granted full immu- nity and paid no penalties in return for its confession and provision of information to the authorities. That reflects a considerable savings from the a215 million it would otherwise have had to pay as a repeat offender. Action to curb the activities of cartels has been equally active in the United States.2 The Department of Justice has recently imposed a total of more than $732 million on companies operating a cartel to control the pricing of dynamic random access memory (DRAM).
    [Show full text]