00465-9781455236213.Pdf

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

00465-9781455236213.Pdf MASTER FILES ROOM C-525 0440 This is a Working Paper and the author would welcome any IMF WORKING PAPER comments on the present text Citations should refer to a Working Paper of the International Monetary Fund, men- tioning the author, and the date of issuance. The views © 1993 International Monetary Fund expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily represent those of the Fund. WP/93/ 12 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Research Department Auctions: Theory and Possible Applications to Economies in Transition Prepared by Robert A. Feldman and Rajnish Mehra Authorized for Distribution by Mohsin S. Khan February 1993 Abstract A major effort is taking place in many parts of the world to establish market-oriented institutions, a development that is particularly evident in the context of the transforming economies in Eastern Europe and the republics of the former Soviet Union. Against this background, this paper assesses various auction techniques to price and allocate government securities, refinance credit, foreign exchange, and state assets in the context of privatization programs. Before making our recommendations on the appropriate format for auctioning these items, the paper explains basic auction formats and assesses the advantages and disadvantages of these formats drawing on the existing, and mostly theoretical, literature. JEL Classification Numbers: C70, D40, D44, D60, P21, P23, P50 *Rajnish Mehra is Professor of Finance at the University of California at Santa Barbara. A first draft of this paper was completed while Professor Mehra was a visiting scholar in the Research Department. The authors would like to thank Eduardo Borensztein, V.V. Chari, Edward Dumas, Chi-fu Huang, Peter Isard, Mohsin S. Khan, Paul Milgrom, Merton Miller, Edward Prescott, Cheng-Zhong Qin and Vincent Reinhart for numerous helpful discussions and suggestions. David Cheney and E. Catherine Fleck provided useful editorial advice. Any errors are the authors' responsibility. The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the International Monetary Fund. - ii - Table of Contents Page Summary iii I. Introduction 1 II. Types of Auctions 3 1. English Auction 3 2. Dutch Auction 3 3. First-Price Auction 4 4. Second-Price Auction 4 III. Auction Theory 6 1. The bidder's perspective 8 (a) Private-value assumption 8 (b) Common-value assumption 8 2. The seller's perspective 9 (a) Private-value assumption 9 (b) Common-value assumption 10 3. Efficiency considerations 12 4. Collusion 13 IV. Applications 15 1. Government securities 15 2. Refinance credit 18 3. Foreign exchange 20 4. Privatization 21 V. Summary and Conclusions 22 Table 1. Selected Characteristics of Different Types of Auctions 7 Figure 1. Auction Formats 4a References 24-26 - iii - Summary A major effort is taking place in many parts of the world to establish and improve market-oriented institutions. This development is particularly evident in the context of the transforming economies in Eastern Europe and the states of the former Soviet Union. Auction mechanisms are useful as one way of guiding price determination and the allocation process in a market- oriented setting. Indeed, introducing auction techniques for various commodities and assets can be used to help acclimate economic agents to operating in a world of market-determined and changing prices. One of the main goals of this paper is to survey the extensive literature on auctions in order to shed some light on the advantages and disadvantages of various auction techniques. A second goal is to assess the application of alternative auction techniques to four specific assets, namely, government securities, refinance credit, foreign exchange, and state assets in the context of privatization. In the process, the paper explains basic auction formats and tries to clarify some of the confusion that can arise because of the differing terminology applied to these formats. The paper concludes that auctions offer advantages of simplicity in determining market-clearing prices where markets may otherwise not exist and in allocating the auctioned items efficiently. The appropriate choice of auction format is less clear. This ambiguity stems in part from the difficulties in applying the theoretical literature to real world settings, and in part from the importance of individual country circumstances. When all is said and done, there are no unambiguous answers to the question of what is the best auction technique to use; this paper has tried, however, to rank the various auction formats according to their appropriateness in different circumstances. On balance, uniform second-price auctions are the preferred technique. They are simpler, perform well in terms of the expected revenue to sellers, and may offer considerable gains in promoting economic efficiency. In some circumstances, the English, ascending-price auction is more favorable but, at the same time, may be difficult to use because of technical consider- ations. English auctions are also more prone to collusive behavior. Discriminatory auctions would tend to be appropriate only in cases where collusion was considered to be a problem. The paper describes the advantages of double auctions in the case of foreign exchange. It emphasizes that irrespective of the choice of auction technique, every effort needs to be made to ensure that auctions are run on a competitive basis with safeguards against monopoly positions. This page intentionally left blank I. Introduction Auctions play an important role in economics. In their most basic form, they are simply one of the ways in which various commodities and financial assets are allocated to individuals and firms, particularly in a market-oriented setting. Examples of items that are commonly auctioned include original art, livestock, fresh fish, used cars, construction contracts, and a range of financial assets such as government securities, central bank refinance credit, foreign exchange, and equity shares. These items exhibit considerable diversity, but a common denominator among them is that the valuation of each item varies enough to preclude any direct and straightforward pricing schedule. The use of auction mechanisms to guide price determination and the allocation process has been associated with the major effort taking place in many parts of the world to establish market-oriented institutions. This development is particularly evident in the context of the transforming economies in Eastern Europe and the former republics of the Soviet Union. Examples of where auctions are particularly relevant include financial instruments such as Treasury (or government) securities, refinance credit, and foreign exchange, and state assets in the context of privatization. As the literature on auctions is extensive, one of the main goals of this paper is to survey and draw on this literature in order to shed some light on the advantages and disadvantages of various auction techniques. I/ A second main goal is to assess the application of alternative auction techniques to the four items mentioned above. We emphasize that the implications of theoretical models do not easily carry over into real world settings. Therefore, our recommendations on the appropriate auction technique for different assets depend heavily on individual country circumstances. Indeed, the array of country experience would suggest that there is no clearcut answer to the question of what is the appropriate auction technique. In this connection, it is instructive to note that in looking at the individual country experience across a range of countries--both industrial and developing--techniques used to auction similar items vary considerably. I/ Reviews of the literature on auctions in different contexts can be found elsewhere, and our paper builds on the insights of these authors. See Maskin (1992), McAfee and McMillan (1987), Milgrom (1985 and 1989), Milgrom and Weber (1982) and Smith (1987). In relation to recent assessments of the U.S. Government securities market, excellent reviews of selected aspects of auction techniques are contained in Bikhchandani and Huang (1992), Chari and Weber (1992), Reinhart (1992) and the Joint Report on the Government Securities Market (1992). - 2 - This experience includes several countries that in auctioning government securities have awarded them at whatever price was bid (e.g., France, Germany, Japan, and the United Kingdom), while others have charged a single, market-clearing price (e.g., Denmark and Switzerland). I/ Some countries have recently changed the way they run their auctions. In this regard, Mexico shifted from a multiple-price to a uniform-price approach in 1990 for Treasury bills, and then in 1993 shifted back. 2/ Italy, in 1991, switched from uniform to multiple pricing in its local-currency Treasury bill auctions, while Treasury bonds and ECU-denominated bills are auctioned on a uniform price basis. Currently, in the United States, the Treasury is experimenting with uniform price auctions for some government securities while also running discriminatory auctions. Relevant examples are also found for foreign exchange and refinance credit. Several countries have conducted discriminatory price or Dutch auctions for refinance credit (Romania) and for foreign exchange (Bolivia, Ghana, Jamaica, and Zambia). Other countries have used uniform price auctions for refinance credit (the former Czechoslovakia) and for foreign exchange (Guinea, Nigeria, and Uganda). 1/4/ Double auctions have been used for foreign exchange (Romania).
Recommended publications
  • MICROECONOMICS and POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H
    MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001 Auctions Wednesday, February 14 Reading: Handout, Thaler, Milgram There are two basic forms of auctions: Sealed bid submissions and open bids. In a sealed bid auction individuals do not know what others are bidding. Two types of Sealed Bid Auctions: 1st Price sealed bid auction: The highest bid submitted will be the winning bid. The winner pays what he/she bid. 2nd Price sealed bid auction: Everyone submits sealed bids and the winner is the one who submits the highest bid BUT the price paid by the winner is the 2nd highest bid submitted. Two types of open auctions: English auction: The bidding starts low and incrementally rises until someone is the highest bidder and no one is willing to outbid the highest bidder. Dutch auction: The price starts very high and is keeps going down until someone bids. The first person to bid wins. Why Study Auctions? 1) Auctions can be an efficient method of valuing goods. For example: rights to air waves, signals and bandwidth. The government auctioned off parts of the spectrum in anticipation of new technology. The auctions were appealing because well- structured auctions get people to reveal the true valuation of the good. The company (private entity) actually ends up paying to the government what the good is worth to them. It turned out with these auctions that the willingness to pay for a slice of the spectrum, as revealed by the auction outcome, was much higher than expected. 2) Procurement: Governments and entities want to procure goods and services at the lowest possible price (like an auction in reverse).
    [Show full text]
  • A Fair and Secure Reverse Auction for Government Procurement
    sustainability Article A Fair and Secure Reverse Auction for Government Procurement Chia-Chen Lin 1,*, Ya-Fen Chang 2, Chin-Chen Chang 3 and Yao-Zhu Zheng 4 1 Department of Computer Science and Information Engineering, National Chin-Yi University of Technology, Taichung 41170, Taiwan 2 Department of Computer Science and Information Engineering, National Taichung University of Science and Technology, Taichung 40401, Taiwan; [email protected] 3 Department of Information Engineering and Computer Science, Feng Chia University, Taichung 40724, Taiwan; [email protected] 4 Department of Computer Science, National Tsing Hua University, Hsinchu 30013, Taiwan; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 21 August 2020; Accepted: 12 October 2020; Published: 16 October 2020 Abstract: With the development of e-commerce, the electronic auction is attracting the attention of many people. Many Internet companies, such as eBay and Yahoo!, have launched online auction systems. Many researchers have studied the security problems of electronic auction systems, but few of them are multi-attribute-based. In 2014, Shi proposed a provable secure, sealed-bid, and multi-attribute auction protocol based on the semi-honest model. We evaluated this protocol and found that it has some design weaknesses and is vulnerable to the illegal operations of buyers, which results in unfairness. In this paper, we improved this protocol by replacing the Paillier’s cryptosystem with the elliptic curve discrete (ECC), and we designed a novel, online, and multi-attribute reverse-auction system using the semi-honest model. In our system, sellers’ identities are not revealed to the buyers, and the buyers cannot conduct illegal operations that may compromise the fairness of the auction.
    [Show full text]
  • Shill Bidding in English Auctions
    Shill Bidding in English Auctions Wenli Wang Zoltan´ Hidvegi´ Andrew B. Whinston Decision and Information Analysis, Goizueta Business School, Emory University, Atlanta, GA, 30322 Center for Research on Electronic Commerce, Department of MSIS, The University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78712 ¡ wenli [email protected] ¡ [email protected] [email protected] First version: January, 2001 Current revision: September 6, 2001 Shill bidding in English auction is the deliberate placing bids on the seller’s behalf to artificially drive up the price of his auctioned item. Shill bidding has been known to occur in auctions of high-value items like art and antiques where bidders’ valuations differ and the seller’s payoff from fraud is high. We prove that private- value English auctions with shill bidding can result in a higher expected seller profit than first and second price sealed-bid auctions. To deter shill bidding, we introduce a mechanism which makes shill bidding unprofitable. The mechanism emphasizes the role of an auctioneer who charges the seller a commission fee based on the difference between the winning bid and the seller’s reserve. Commission rates vary from market to market and are mathematically determined to guarantee the non-profitability of shill bidding. We demonstrate through examples how this mechanism works and analyze the seller’s optimal strategy. The Internet provides auctions accessible to the general pub- erature on auction theories, which currently are insufficient to lic. Anyone can easily participate in online auctions, either as guide online practices. a seller or a buyer, and the value of items sold ranges from a One of the emerging issues is shill bidding, which has become few dollars to millions.
    [Show full text]
  • Game Theory 2021
    More Mechanism Design Game Theory 2021 Game Theory 2021 Ulle Endriss Institute for Logic, Language and Computation University of Amsterdam Ulle Endriss 1 More Mechanism Design Game Theory 2021 Plan for Today In this second lecture on mechanism design we are going to generalise beyond the basic scenario of auctions|as much as we can manage: • Revelation Principle: can focus on direct-revelation mechanisms • formal model of direct-revelation mechanisms with money • incentive compatibility of the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves mechanism • other properties of VCG for special case of combinatorial auctions • impossibility of achieving incentive compatibility more generally Much of this is also (somewhat differently) covered by Nisan (2007). N. Nisan. Introduction to Mechanism Design (for Computer Scientists). In N. Nisan et al. (eds.), Algorithmic Game Theory. Cambridge University Press, 2007. Ulle Endriss 2 More Mechanism Design Game Theory 2021 Reminder Last time we saw four auction mechanisms for selling a single item: English, Dutch, first-price sealed-bid, Vickrey. The Vickrey auction was particularly interesting: • each bidder submits a bid in a sealed envelope • the bidder with the highest bid wins, but pays the price of the second highest bid (unless it's below the reservation price) It is a direct-revelation mechanism (unlike English and Dutch auctions) and it is incentive-compatible, i.e., truth-telling is a dominant strategy (unlike for Dutch and FPSB auctions). Ulle Endriss 3 More Mechanism Design Game Theory 2021 The Revelation Principle Revelation Principle: Any outcome that is implementable in dominant strategies via some mechanism can also be implemented by means of a direct-revelation mechanism making truth-telling a dominant strategy.
    [Show full text]
  • And Information Aggregation)
    Introduction to Auctions (and information aggregation) Saša Pekeč Decision Sciences The Fuqua School of Business Duke University October 29, 2008 Outline of the Topics •Scoring rules • Prediction markets • Auctions: clean and oversimplifying view • Auctions: messy but closer to reality • Information aggregation results Information Aggregation • Surveys • Opinion Polls • Aggregating votes / ratings / review scores / … • Eliciting and aggregating expert opinions … Issues: • info quantity • info quality • representativeness • incentives Single Data Point Info Quality •stats • machine learning Add incentives: Example: Binary event E (thumbs up/down, yes/no, 0/1) Elicit probability estimate of E=1: p. Brier score: B(p)= 1-(E-p)2 If r reported instead of p: E[B(r)|p]= p(1-(1-r)2)+(1-p)(1-r2) maximized at r=p ( d/dr : 2p(1-r)-2(1-p)r ) Truthful reporting maximizes Brier score Scoring Rules • Consider a probability forecast for a discrete event with n possible outcomes (“states of the world”). • Let ei = (0, ..., 1, ..., 0) denote the indicator vector for the ith state (where 1 appears in the ith position). • Let p = (p1, ..., pn) denote the forecaster’s true subjective probability distribution over states. • Let r = (r1, ..., rn) denote the forecaster’s reported distribution (if different from p). (Also, let q = (q1, ..., qn) denote a baseline distribution upon which the forecaster seeks to improve.) Slide thx to R.Nau Proper Scoring Rules • The scoring rule S is [strictly] proper if S(p) ≥ [>] S(r, p) for all r [≠p], i.e., if the forecaster’s expected score is [uniquely] maximized when she reports her true probabilities.
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Auctions Protocols Revenue and Optimal Auctions Common Value Auctions
    Auctions Kate Larson Introduction Auction Protocols Common Auction Introduction to Auctions Protocols Revenue and Optimal Auctions Common Value Auctions Vulnerabilities Kate Larson in Auctions Beyond Single Cheriton School of Computer Science Item Auctions University of Waterloo Summary Outline Auctions Kate Larson 1 Introduction Introduction Auction Protocols 2 Auction Protocols Common Auction Protocols Common Auction Protocols Revenue and Optimal Auctions Common Value Revenue and Optimal Auctions Auctions Common Value Auctions Vulnerabilities in Auctions Beyond Single 3 Vulnerabilities in Auctions Item Auctions Summary 4 Beyond Single Item Auctions 5 Summary Auctions Auctions Kate Larson Methods for allocating goods, tasks, resources,... Introduction Participants Auction auctioneer Protocols Common Auction bidders Protocols Revenue and Optimal Auctions Enforced agreement between auctioneer and the Common Value Auctions winning bidder(s) Vulnerabilities in Auctions Easily implementable (e.g. over the Internet) Beyond Single Conventions Item Auctions Summary Auction: one seller and multiple buyers Reverse auction: one buyer and multiple sellers Todays lecture will discuss the theory in the context of auctions, but this applies to reverce auctions as well (at least in 1-item settings). Auction Settings Auctions Kate Larson Introduction Private value: the value of the good depends only on Auction the agent’s own preferences Protocols e.g a cake that is not resold of showed off Common Auction Protocols Revenue and Common value: an agent’s value of an item is Optimal Auctions Common Value determined entirely by others’ values (valuation of the Auctions item is identical for all agents) Vulnerabilities in Auctions e.g. treasury bills Beyond Single Item Auctions Correlated value (interdependent value): agent’s Summary value for an item dpends partly on its own preferences and partly on others’ value for it e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Reverse Live Auction for Bidder
    Process for Reverse Live Auction What is Reverse Live Auction? Reverse Live Auction (RLA) implemented in the Chhattisgarh State Power Companies uses Supplier Relationship Management (SRM) module of SAP (globally Known ERP). RLA provides a real-time environment which drives bottom-line results significantly by putting suppliers into direct competition with each other. Transaction type “English Auction” is used in RLA which works on principal “New Bid Must Beat Overall Best Bid”. RLA have the provision of setting up the auction with automatic extensions that is if the bid is submitted within few minutes/seconds of the auction end time. The auction end time will automatically get extended, based on the timing parameters fixed by purchaser. Automatic Extension of end time in RLA is based on below given 3 parameters defined by Purchaser and also visible to bidders once the RLA is published: • Remaining Time Trigger: This field refers to the duration of time (minutes), before which Reverse Live Auction is programmed to end, if a new bid is placed within this time duration, the RLA will be extended with specified time (Extension Period). • Extension Period: The span of time (hours or minutes) by which the system extends an RLA, if a bid is received during “Remaining Time Trigger” period. • Number of Extensions: This field depicts the maximum number of times by which an auction can be extended automatically. Process for Reverse Live Auction Please follow the below given steps to configure Java to run the “Live Auction Cockpit” in case the Application is blocked by JAVA: 1. Go to Control Panel > Double click on JAVA to open.
    [Show full text]
  • The Ability of Dutch Foreclosure Auctions in Maximizing Seller Revenue
    The ability of Dutch foreclosure auctions in maximizing seller revenue Why Dutch foreclosure auction prices fall short of the market price Martijn Duijster 0475211 Group 2 Finance, semester 2, 2013-2014 17-7-2014 Bachelor thesis Economics and Business - specialization Finance and Organization Sander Onderstal Faculty of Economics and Business University of Amsterdam Index Abstract 3 1. Introduction 3 2. Dutch real estate auctions 4 3. Literature review 6 3.1. Types of auctions 6 3.2. The revenue equivalence results 8 3.3. Violations of the revenue equivalence result assumption 8 3.3.1. Information asymmetry 9 3.3.2. Competition 10 3.3.3. Bidder affiliation and the winner’s curse 11 4. Hypotheses 12 5. Research method 13 6. Results 15 6.1.. Explanation of the results 17 6.1.1. Information asymmetry 17 6.1.2. Competition 18 6.1.3 Solutions to improve competition 18 6.1.4. Transaction costs 19 6.1.5 Conflicts of interest between seller and owner 21 7. Conclusion 22 References 24 Appendices 26 2 Abstract The revenues in Dutch foreclosure auctions are compared to the market values of the properties. The discount rate is calculated which states the difference between the auction price and the market price. Foreclosure auctions in the Netherlands fail to receive an auction price close to the market price; the average discount rate with auction cost included in the auction price is about 20% and the discount rate when auction costs are excluded is about 27%. Asymmetric information, lack of competition, transaction costs and conflicts of interest may be attributable to this price gap.
    [Show full text]
  • Auction Theory
    Auction Theory Jonathan Levin October 2004 Our next topic is auctions. Our objective will be to cover a few of the main ideas and highlights. Auction theory can be approached from different angles – from the perspective of game theory (auctions are bayesian games of incomplete information), contract or mechanism design theory (auctions are allocation mechanisms), market microstructure (auctions are models of price formation), as well as in the context of different applications (procure- ment, patent licensing, public finance, etc.). We’re going to take a relatively game-theoretic approach, but some of this richness should be evident. 1 The Independent Private Value (IPV) Model 1.1 A Model The basic auction environment consists of: Bidders i =1,...,n • Oneobjecttobesold • Bidder i observes a “signal” Si F ( ), with typical realization si • [s, s], and assume F is continuous.∼ · ∈ Bidders’ signals S1,...,Sn are independent. • Bidder i’s value vi(si)=si. • Given this basic set-up, specifying a set of auction rules will give rise to a game between the bidders. Before going on, observe two features of the model that turn out to be important. First, bidder i’s information (her signal) is independent of bidder j’s information. Second, bidder i’s value is independent of bidder j’s information – so bidder j’s information is private in the sense that it doesn’t affect anyone else’s valuation. 1 1.2 Vickrey (Second-Price) Auction In a Vickrey, or second price, auction, bidders are asked to submit sealed bids b1,...,bn. The bidder who submits the highest bid is awarded the object, and pays the amount of the second highest bid.
    [Show full text]
  • English and Vickrey Auctions
    CHAPTER ONE English and Vickrey Auctions I describe a bit of the history of auctions, the two pairs of standard auction forms, and the ideas of dominance and strategic equivalence. 1.1 Auctions It is hard to imagine modern civilization without buying and selling, which make possible the division of labor and its consequent wealth (Smith, 1776). For many common and relatively inexpensive commodi­ ties, the usual and convenient practice at the retail level, in the West anyway, is simply for the seller to post a take-it-or-leave-it price, and for the prospective buyer to choose what to buy and where to buy it, perhaps shopping for favorable prices. I haven’t tried haggling over price at a Wal-Mart, but I can’t imagine it would get me very far. For some big-ticket items, however, like houses and cars, haggling and counteroffers are expected, even in polite society, and bargaining can be extended over many rounds. In some cultures, haggling is the rule for almost all purchases. A third possibility, our subject here, is the auction, where many prospective buyers compete for the opportunity to purchase items, either simultaneously, or over an extended period of time. The main attraction of the auction is that it can be used to sell things with more or less uncertain market value, like a tractor in a farmer’s estate, a manufacturer’s overrun of shampoo, or the final working copy of Beethoven’s score for his Ninth Symphony (see fig. 1.1). It thus promises to fetch as high a price as possible for the seller, while at the same time offering to the buyer the prospect of buying items at bargain prices, or perhaps buying items that would be difficult to buy in any other way.
    [Show full text]
  • An Experimental Study of the Generalized Second Price Auction
    An experimental study of the generalized second price auction. Jinsoo Bae John H. Kagel The Ohio State University The Ohio State University 6/18/2018 Abstract We experimentally investigate the Generalized Second Price (GSP) auction used to sell advertising positions in online search engines. Two contrasting click through rates (CTRs) are studied, under both static complete and dynamic incomplete information settings. Subjects consistently bid above the Vikrey-Clarke-Grove’s (VCG) like equilibrium favored in the theoretical literature. However, bidding, at least qualitatively, satisfies the contrasting outcomes predicted under the two contrasting CTRs. For both CTRs, outcomes under the static complete information environment are similar to those in later rounds of the dynamic incomplete information environment. This supports the theoretical literature that uses the static complete information model as an approximation to the dynamic incomplete information under which advertising positions are allocated in field settings. We are grateful to Linxin Ye, Jim Peck, Paul J Healy, Kirby Nielsen, Ritesh Jain for valuable comments. This research has been partially supported by NSF grant SES Foundation, SES- 1630288 and grants from the Department of Economics at The Ohio state University. Previous versions of this paper were reported at the 2017 ESA North American Meetings in Richmond, VA. We alone are responsible for any errors or omissions in the research reported. 1 1. Introduction Search engines such as Google, Yahoo and Microsoft sell advertisement slots on their search result pages through auctions, among which the Generalized Second Price (GSP) auction is the most prevalent format. Under GSP auctions, advertisers submit a single per-click bid.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Double Auction
    Optimal Double Auction Alex Boulatov1, Terrence Hendershott2, and Dmitry Livdan3 1Center for Advanced Studies, Higher School of Economics, Moscow. email: [email protected]. 2Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley. email: [email protected]. 3Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley. email: [email protected]. Optimal Double Auction [Very Preliminary] Abstract We consider a private value double-auction model which can be viewed as an extension of the model of Riley and Samuelson (1981) to the case of multiple sellers. Each seller has one unit of the same asset for sale and buyers compete to purchase one unit of the asset from one of the sellers. In the model sellers costlessly adjust their reserve prices, while sequentially moving buyers optimally choose between sellers to maximize their respective expected payoffs. The reserve price plays the role of a choice variable in the model, for both types of players. The refinement we propose in this paper is based on the following trade-off. From the sellers' perspective the probability of selling the good is increasing in the number of buyers bidding for it and, therefore, sellers have the incentive to decrease their reserve price to attract more buyers. From buyers' perspective, the probability of winning the auction decreases in the number of buyers and therefore buyers with higher private valuations are better off choosing sellers with slightly higher reserve price but fewer number of buyers. We exploit this trade-off to construct the symmetric Nash equilibrium in pure strategies in this double auction. Our first result is that such equilibrium exists and it is unique in the case of two sellers and the even number of buyers and it does not exist when the number of buyers is odd.
    [Show full text]