Price Predation: Legal Limits and Antitrust Considerations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Price Predation: Legal Limits and Antitrust Considerations Price Predation: Legal Limits and Antitrust Considerations Gregory T. Gundlach Competition centered strategies in the form of predatory pricing directed toward weakening or destroying a competitor are receiving increasing emphasis in the Courts and among antitrust theorists and policymakers. Recently, the Supreme Court found little evidence of antitrust injury e.xtending from price predation in the case fj/Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corporation (1993). The author examines the current legal .standard for predatory pricing and juxtaposes it against emerging insights on this competitive practice. n markeling. cotnpetition-centered strategies, including below-cost levels, discriminatory pricing, and temporary the manipulation of price, have received increasing em- price warring. I phasis (cf. Weitz 1985). According to Kotler and Singh A primary objective of the antitrust laws is to distinguish (1981, p. 30). "successful marketing ... require[s] devising competitive strategies (and more particularly, predatory competition-centered strategies, not just customer-centered strategies) that are welfare enhancing from those that reduce and distribution-centered strategies." Faced with declining the welfare of consumers. The difficulty of this task is made market growth, resource scarcities, and the proliferation of even more complicated when predatory pricing is involved. new technologies, companies are increasingly pursuing The Supreme Court states: profit gains at the expense of their rivals through market share rather than market growth. [TJhe mechanism by which a firm engages in predatory pric- ing—lowering prices—is the same mechanism by which a firm Strategies directed toward competitors can involve differ- stimulates competition; because cutting prices in order to in- ent objectives. On the one hand, a company may employ crease business often is the very essence of competition ...[;] competition-centered strategies to create a "better state of mistaken inferences ... are especially costly, because they chill peace" hetween rivals (Kotler and Singh 1981). Such an ap- the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect proach involves a business entrenching itself in some part of {Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. the market in which it has a natural and comparative advan- 1993. p. 4703). tage. This advantage discourages aggressive actions by ri- Because of the possibility of mistaking welfare enhancing vals and favors peaceful coexistence. Rivalrous behavior price competition and extant theory that suggests the irra- that does occur is usually the result of one firm poorly serv- tionality of predatory pricing, policymakers and the Courts ing its market niche, a new competitor attempting to bring have long held a skeptical view of this form of (anti)compe- new advantages to the market, or changes occurring in the tition. Their thesis is that a predator would lo.se so much environment. Strategies of this kind are welfare enhancing, money attempting to drive out a rival through lt)wering price because they facilitate efficient competition. below cost that it would never eam enough profits later to On the other hand, competitive strategies may also pos- recoup its losses. The argued irrationality toward predatory sess the objective of weakening or destroying a competitor pricing and resultant enforcement posture taken by the De- (i.e.. cutthroat competition). These strategies can be injuri- partment of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commis- ous to competition and may potentially reduce consumer sion (FTC) (see Rule 1988) is summarized by a former di- welfare. Such strategies are commonly referred to as preda- rector of the Bureau of Competition: "Many argue that pre- tion OT predatory strategies and can involve both price and dation is impossible, and hence, enforcement of the antimo- nonprice tactics (cf. ZeithamI and ZeithamI 1984). Nonprice nopolization provisions of the Sherman Act should not be predation involves a competitor's attempt to increase a based on this empty concept" (Campbell 1987, p. 1625). rival's costs through such tactics as the acquisition and This perspective also underlies key decisions of the "sleeping on" of patents, predatory product preannounce- Supreme Court, which has stated, "predatory pricing ... is by ments, useless product modifications, exclusionary market nature speculative ... landl ... rarely tried, and even more channel arrangements, disparaging advertising, and sham rarely successful" (Matsushita Electric industrial Co. v. litigation (see Gundlach 1990). An aggressive firm may also Zenith Radio Corp. 1986. pp. 588-89). attempt to lower a rival's profits through price predation. In Recently, the Supreme Court again addressed predatory this case, a firm sets its prices low enough and for a suffi- pricing in Brooke Gmup v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Cor- cient time period to disadvantage its rivals in some way poration (1993). In announcing a two-part standard, the Court (Sheffet 1994). Tactics can include sustained price cuts lo found little evidence of predation in a price war between two major tobacco companies. The Court's decision establishes a very difficult threshold for firms threatened by predatory pric- GREGORY T. GUNDLACH is an associate professor. Department of ing. Some commentators have even suggested that the impact Marketing. University of Notre Dame. The author thanks the edi- of the ca.se as a precedent may prove to be "fatal to all future tor, four JPP&M reviewers, the members of the Department of predatory pricing claims" (Glazer 1994. p. 606). Marketing at the University of Notre Dame, and especially Joseph P. Guiltinan and Debra J. Ringold for their helpful comments. In contrast to the Supreme Court's holding and those commentators espousing such a view, a number of theorists Vol. 14 (2) 278 Joumal of Public Policy & Marketing Fall 1995, 278-289 Journal of Public Policy & Marketing 279 have begun to reconsider the nature and occurrence of pre- predatory pricing, a firm is prohibited from selling at a low dation as an anticompetitive practice. Among these scholars, price when it encounters competition and at a high price oth- "il is now generally agreed that the argument that predation erwise if its purpose is to drive rivals out of the market. In is impossihle is incorrect at least as a matter of theory" (Hay addition, other discriminatory practices aimed at forcing a 1990. p. 913). These theorists propose numerous models of competitor to consolidate or disciplining a rival that reduced predation that rely on nonstatic notions of competition in- its prices or competed with the firm are forbidden. volving multiple markets, asymmetries of information, and Section 5 of the FTC Act (1914) autborizes ibe Commis- nonprofit maximizing strategies (see Schmalensee and sion to cballenge predatory practices deemed to be "unfair Willig 1989). According to this "new learning." in theory, metbods of competition." Tbe Act permits (I) challenges to even above-cost pricing can be employed to disadvantage predatory conduct violating the Sherman and Clayton Acts equally or more efficient rivals and result in injury to con- and (2) transgressions of the spirit of these Acts. sumer welfare (Hay 1990. p. 914). Of course, the desirabil- Besides the federal laws, many states have sales-below- ity of adopting and implementing such an antitrust standard cost statutes or constitutions prohibiting monopolies that is questionable. (For a discussion of this issue, see. for ex- can be employed to cballenge predatory pricing (see Haynes ample. Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grlnnel Corp. 1983.) 1990). Often, these statutes require evidence of below-cost However, tbe insight offered by scholars of this paradigm pricing and a specific intent to injure a competitor. For ex- bas prompted some to reconsider prior antitrust thinking. ample, in a recent well-publicized case. Wal-Mart. Ameri- I examine the current law and theory of predatory pricing, ca's leading discounter, was found guilty of violating an while emphasizing the Supreme Court's two-part standard Arkansas state unfair pricing statute: Its stated pricing strat- developed in Brooke Group (1993). This standard is juxta- egy was to "meet or beat tbe competition without regard to posed against recent advancements in industrial organiza- cost" (American Drugs. Inc. v. Wal-Mart Stores. Inc. 1993). tion theory and marketing that describe how predatory con- Courts have observed these unfair pricing laws to ease the duct involving price may be a rational strategy for tbe ag- hardships of cutthroat competition (Quinn 1990). gressive competitor and may be employed in a variety of ways to disadvantage rivals, some of which create antitrust Federal Standards injury. I then discuss implications for antitrust policy devel- At the Federal level, differences among the statutory lan- opment, marketing research, and the practice of markeling. guage of botb the Sherman and Clayton Acts bas led to dif- ferent standards for injury to competition and the nature of Background and Current Law conduct considered anticompetitive. Tbe Sbennan Act con- demns predatory pricing when it poses a "dangerous proba- Statutory Law bility of actual monopolization" (Spectrum Sports. Inc. v. Federal antitrust law attempts to control predation through McQuillan 1993. p. 8). In contrast, tbe Robinson-Patman Section 2 of the Sherman Act (1890). Section 2 of the Clay- Act requires only "a reasonable possibility" of substantial ton Act (1914)
Recommended publications
  • The FTC and the Law of Monopolization
    George Mason University School of Law Law and Economics Research Papers Series Working Paper No. 00-34 2000 The FTC and the Law of Monopolization Timothy J. Muris As published in Antitrust Law Journal, Vol. 67, No. 3, 2000 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection: http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=235403 The FTC and the Law of Monopolization by Timothy J. Muris Although Microsoft has attracted much more attention, recent developments at the FTC may have a greater impact on the law of monopolization. From recent pronouncements, the agency appears to believe that in monopolization cases government proof of anticompetitive effect is unnecessary. In one case, the Commission staff argued that defendants should not even be permitted to argue that its conduct lacks an anticompetitive impact. This article argues that the FTC's position is wrong on the law, on policy, and on the facts. Courts have traditionally required full analysis, including consideration of whether the practice in fact has an anticompetitive impact. Even with such analysis, the courts have condemned practices that in retrospect appear not to have been anticompetitive. Given our ignorance about the sources of a firm's success, monopolization cases must necessarily be wide-ranging in their search for whether the conduct at issue in fact created, enhanced, or preserved monopoly power, whether efficiency justifications explain such behavior, and all other relevant issues. THE FTC AND THE LAW OF MONOPOLIZATION Timothy J. Muris* I. INTRODUCTION Most government antitrust cases involve collaborative activity. Collabo- ration between competitors, whether aimed at sti¯ing some aspect of rivalry, such as ®xing prices, or ending competition entirely via merger, is the lifeblood of antitrust.
    [Show full text]
  • Amazon's Antitrust Paradox
    LINA M. KHAN Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox abstract. Amazon is the titan of twenty-first century commerce. In addition to being a re- tailer, it is now a marketing platform, a delivery and logistics network, a payment service, a credit lender, an auction house, a major book publisher, a producer of television and films, a fashion designer, a hardware manufacturer, and a leading host of cloud server space. Although Amazon has clocked staggering growth, it generates meager profits, choosing to price below-cost and ex- pand widely instead. Through this strategy, the company has positioned itself at the center of e- commerce and now serves as essential infrastructure for a host of other businesses that depend upon it. Elements of the firm’s structure and conduct pose anticompetitive concerns—yet it has escaped antitrust scrutiny. This Note argues that the current framework in antitrust—specifically its pegging competi- tion to “consumer welfare,” defined as short-term price effects—is unequipped to capture the ar- chitecture of market power in the modern economy. We cannot cognize the potential harms to competition posed by Amazon’s dominance if we measure competition primarily through price and output. Specifically, current doctrine underappreciates the risk of predatory pricing and how integration across distinct business lines may prove anticompetitive. These concerns are height- ened in the context of online platforms for two reasons. First, the economics of platform markets create incentives for a company to pursue growth over profits, a strategy that investors have re- warded. Under these conditions, predatory pricing becomes highly rational—even as existing doctrine treats it as irrational and therefore implausible.
    [Show full text]
  • The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H
    University of Baltimore Law ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law All Faculty Scholarship Faculty Scholarship 2000 The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules Robert H. Lande University of Baltimore School of Law, [email protected] Howard P. Marvel Ohio State University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarworks.law.ubalt.edu/all_fac Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation The Three Types of Collusion: Fixing Prices, Rivals, and Rules, 2000 Wis. L. Rev. 941 (2000) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks@University of Baltimore School of Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ARTICLES THE THREE TYPES OF COLLUSION: FIXING PRICES, RIVALS, AND RULES ROBERTH. LANDE * & HOWARDP. MARVEL** Antitrust law has long held collusion to be paramount among the offenses that it is charged with prohibiting. The reason for this prohibition is simple----collusion typically leads to monopoly-like outcomes, including monopoly profits that are shared by the colluding parties. Most collusion cases can be classified into two established general categories.) Classic, or "Type I" collusion involves collective action to raise price directly? Firms can also collude to disadvantage rivals in a manner that causes the rivals' output to diminish or causes their behavior to become chastened. This "Type 11" collusion in turn allows the colluding firms to raise prices.3 Many important collusion cases, however, do not fit into either of these categories.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Evidence on Predatory Pricing Policies
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Edlin, Aaron S.; Roux, Catherine; Schmutzler, Armin; Thöni, Christian Working Paper Hunting unicorns? Experimental evidence on predatory pricing policies Working Paper, No. 258 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Zurich Suggested Citation: Edlin, Aaron S.; Roux, Catherine; Schmutzler, Armin; Thöni, Christian (2017) : Hunting unicorns? Experimental evidence on predatory pricing policies, Working Paper, No. 258, University of Zurich, Department of Economics, Zurich, http://dx.doi.org/10.5167/uzh-138188 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/173418 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper Series ISSN 1664-7041 (print) ISSN 1664-705X (online) Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Predatory Pricing, a Case Study: Matsushita Electric Industries Co. V. Zenith Radio Corporation
    PREDATORY PRICING, A CASE STUDY: MATSUSHITA ELECTRIC INDUSTRIES CO. V. ZENITH RADIO CORPORATION M. STEVEN WAGLE INTRODUCTION There is an abundance of predatory pricing theories. Scholars have created a barrage of rules and thresholds designed to detect un- lawful predatory practices. The most influential work on predatory practice was written almost thirty years ago by John S. McGee.1 Mc- Gee showed that although it was widely believed that the Standard Oil Company used predatory pricing in its virtual monopolization of the oil refining market, there was no hard evidence to show that Standard Oil in fact employed such pricing. Since McGee, many scholars have reviewed the theories of pric- ing, and recent literature on the law and economics of antitrust has devoted increasing attention to this issue.2 There has also been an outpouring of cost-based rules appearing in court opinions dealing with predatory pricing.3 These rules can essentially be attributed to t J.D., Washburn University, 1986; M.A., Wichita State University, 1986; B.A., Unmversity of Kansas, 1980. Law clerk to the Hon. John K. Pearson, Wichita, Kansas. I would like to thank Dr. Philip Hersch, Professor of Economics, Wichita State Umver- sity, for patiently reviewing this article and offering invaluable criticism of it. 1. McGee, Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (NJ.) Case, 1 J.L. & EcON. 137 (1958). 2. For additional perspectives, see Areeda & Turner, PredatoryPring and Re- lated Practices Under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 88 HARV. L. REV. 697 (1975); Jos- kow & Klevorick, A Frameworkfor Analyzing PredatoryPrmcng Policy, 89 YALE L.J.
    [Show full text]
  • A Proposal to Enhance Antitrust Protection Against Labor Market Monopsony Roosevelt Institute Working Paper
    A Proposal to Enhance Antitrust Protection Against Labor Market Monopsony Roosevelt Institute Working Paper Ioana Marinescu, University of Pennsylvania Eric A. Posner, University of Chicago1 December 21, 2018 1 We thank Daniel Small, Marshall Steinbaum, David Steinberg, and Nancy Walker and her staff, for helpful comments. 1 The United States has a labor monopsony problem. A labor monopsony exists when lack of competition in the labor market enables employers to suppress the wages of their workers. Labor monopsony harms the economy: the low wages force workers out of the workforce, suppressing economic growth. Labor monopsony harms workers, whose wages and employment opportunities are reduced. Because monopsonists can artificially restrict labor mobility, monopsony can block entry into markets, and harm companies who need to hire workers. The labor monopsony problem urgently calls for a solution. Legal tools are already in place to help combat monopsony. The antitrust laws prohibit employers from colluding to suppress wages, and from deliberately creating monopsonies through mergers and other anticompetitive actions.2 In recent years, the Federal Trade Commission and the Justice Department have awoken from their Rip Van Winkle labor- monopsony slumber, and brought antitrust cases against employers and issued guidance and warnings.3 But the antitrust laws have rarely been used by private litigants because of certain practical and doctrinal weaknesses. And when they have been used—whether by private litigants or by the government—they have been used against only the most obvious forms of anticompetitive conduct, like no-poaching agreements. There has been virtually no enforcement against abuses of monopsony power more generally.
    [Show full text]
  • Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly?
    COVER STORIES Antitrust , Vol. 33, No. 2, Spring 2019. © 2019 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly? BY DEBBIE FEINSTEIN AND ALBERT TENG OR A NUMBER OF YEARS, exists—or only when it can also be shown to harm consumer commentators have debated whether the United welfare; (2) historical case law on monopsony; (3) recent States has a monopoly problem. But as part of the cases involving monopsony issues; and (4) counseling con - recent conversation over the direction of antitrust siderations for monopsony issues. It remains to be seen law and the continued appropriateness of the con - whether we will see significantly increased enforcement Fsumer welfare standard, the debate has turned to whether the against buyer-side agreements and mergers that affect buyer antitrust agencies are paying enough attention to monopsony power and whether such enforcement will be successful, but issues. 1 A concept that appears more in textbooks than in case what is clear is that the antitrust enforcement agencies will be law has suddenly become mainstream and practitioners exploring the depth and reach of these theories and clients should be aware of developments when they counsel clients must be prepared for investigations and enforcement actions on issues involving supply-side concerns. implicating these issues. This topic is not going anywhere any time soon.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance: Economic Theories and Empirical Evidence
    "RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE: ECONOMIC THEORIES AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission November 1983 RESALF. PRICE INTF.NANCE: ECONO IC THEORIES AND PIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commiss ion November 1983 . FEDERAL TRDE COM~ISSION -f. JAMES C. ~ILLER, III, Chairman MICHAEL PERTSCHUK, Commissioner PATRICIA P. BAILEY, Commissioner GEORGE W. DOUGLAS, Commissioner TERRY CALVANI, Commi S5 ioner BUREAU OF ECONO~ICS WENDY GRA~, Director RONALD S. BOND, Deputy Director for Operations and Research RICHARD HIGGINS, Deputy Director for Consumer Protection and Regulatory Analysis JOHN L. PETE , Associate Director for Special Projects DAVID T. SCHEFF N, Deputy Director for Competition and Anti trust PAUL PAUTLER, Assistant to Deputy Director for Competition and Antitrust JOHN E. CALFEE, Special Assistant to the Director JAMES A. HURDLE, Special Assistant to . the Director THOMAS WALTON, Special Assistant to the Director KEITH B. ANDERSON, Assistant Director of Regulatory Analysis JAMES M. FERGUSON, Assistant Director for Antitrust PAULINE IPPOLITO, Assistant Director for Industry Analysis WILLIAM F. LONG, ~anager for Line of Business PHILIP NELSON, Assistant Director for Competition Analysis PAUL H. RUBIN, Assistant Director for Consumer Protection This report has been prepared by an individual member of the professional staff of the FTC Bureau of Economics. It rsfle cts solely the views of the author, and is not intended to represent the position of the Federal Trade Commission, or necessarily the views of any individual Commissioner. -ii - fI. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank former FTC Commissioner David A.
    [Show full text]
  • Guidelines for the Analysis of Cases of Exclusionary Abuse of Dominance
    GUIDELINES FOR THE ANALYSIS OF CASES OF EXCLUSIONARY ABUSE OF DOMINANCE Buenos Aires, Mayo de 2019 Disclaimer: These guidelines have been translated into English to help their reading by non-Spanish speaking people. The only official version of the Argentine Guidelines for the Analysis of Cases of Exclusionary Abuse of Dominance, however, is the Spanish version. 1 CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION 3 II. EXISTENCE OF A DOMINANT POSITION 4 III. ABUSE OF DOMINANC​E 7 III.1. Factors to take into account for the existence of exclusionary abuses of dominance 8 III.2. Efficiencies 9 IV. SPECIFIC FORMS OF ABUSE 10 IV.1. Refusal to supply and margin squeeze 10 IV.2. Tying and bundling 13 IV.3. Predatory pricing 15 IV.4. Vertical restraints 16 IV.4.1.Resale price maintenance 17 IV.4.2. Exclusivity 18 IV.4.3.Conditional discounts 20 2 I. INTRODUCTION The aim of this document is to provide guidelines regarding practices that constitute infringements of Act No. 27,442 of Defense of Competition (LDC, for its Spanish acronym) and to contribute to predictability in decision-making, notwithstanding its application on a case-by-case basis and the use of complementary criteria that may be developed in the future. In this sense, the guidelines set forth in this document do not constitute an opinion regarding specific cases under investigation. A typical classification of the conducts that infringe the LDC differentiates unilateral from coordinated conducts. This document refers only to the first type, in particular, to possible abuses of a dominant position by a single firm or legal entity.
    [Show full text]
  • Essential Facilities, Infrastructure, and Open Access*
    Working Draft for DOJ/FTC Hearings. Do Not Cite without Permission of Authors. Essential Facilities, Infrastructure, and Open Access* Brett Frischmann+ & Spencer Weber Waller++ I. INTRODUCTION There is a debate raging concerning the merits of private control over (or conversely, open access to) various types of resources. Treating something as private property grants the property holder the right to exclude others. Treating something as infrastructure or a commons conversely welcomes all users on a nondiscriminatory basis. The battle over which regime best serves society’s interests exists in numerous areas of the law including land use, intellectual property, regulated industries, antitrust, and most aspects of law and economics. It is currently in vogue to propertize, privatize, and deregulate legal regimes under a variety of rationales all connected with maximizing wealth, supporting price discrimination, promoting allocative efficiency, and internalizing externalities. In intellectual property law, these issues are most prominent in contemporary debates over * © 2006 Brett Frischmann & Spencer Waller. + Assistant Professor, Loyola University Chicago. Thanks to Michael Carrier, Michael Jacobs, Mark Lemley, Christopher Leslie, Frank Pasquale, Phil Weiser and Joshua Wright for their comments on earlier versions of this article. ++ Associate Dean for Faculty Research and Director, Institute for Consumer Antitrust Studies, Loyola University Chicago. Thanks to Lindsay Frank and Jackie Clisham for her research assistance with this project. 1 Working Draft for DOJ/FTC Hearings. Do Not Cite without Permission of Authors. the continued expansion of intellectual property rights.1 The conflict over access and exclusion is a central, persistent feature of intellectual property law. Those who create, invent, innovate, and participate in similar intellectually driven, productive activities often borrow from or share with others.
    [Show full text]
  • Report on Predatory Pricing
    Report on Predatory Pricing Prepared by The Unilateral Conduct Working Group th Presented at the 7 Annual Conference of the ICN Kyoto, April 2008 TABLE OF CONTENTS Executive Summary.......................................................................................................... 3 I. LEGAL BASIS AND ENFORCEMENT................................................................ 5 1. General v. Specific Provisions................................................................................ 5 2. Civil v. Criminal Enforcement................................................................................ 6 3. Overview of Agency and Private Enforcement ...................................................... 7 A. Agency enforcement ........................................................................................... 7 B. Private cases challenging predatory pricing ....................................................... 8 II. CRITERIA FOR ABUSE OF DOMINANCE/MONOPOLIZATION BASED ON PREDATORY PRICING.......................................................................................... 9 1. Use of Cost Measures or Benchmarks to Demonstrate Loss or Sacrifice .............. 9 A. Cost measures employed................................................................................. 9 B. Agencies do not necessarily use the same cost measure in every case......... 12 C. Presumptions and safe harbors.......................................................................... 13 D. Use of price and cost data ................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The European Antitrust Review 2013
    The European Antitrust Review 2013 Published by Global Competition Review in association with Anastasios Antoniou LLC Art De Lex Law Firm Asters bpv Braun Partners bpv Hügel Rechtsanwälte Buntscheck Rechtsanwaltsgesellschaft mbH DLA Piper Italy DLA Piper Spain SL Dryllerakis & Associates Eisenberger & Herzog ELIG Attorneys at Law Epstein, Chomsky, Osnat & Co Gide Loyrette Nouel AARPI Herbert Smith LLP Homburger K & L Gates Karanovic´ & Nikolic´ Kastell Advokatbyrå AB Kavcˇicˇ, Rogl & Bracˇun Kirkland & Ellis International LLP Krogerus Attorneys Ltd Lademann & Associates GmbH Economists and Competition Consultants Latham & Watkins Macfarlanes LLP Monaco & Associati Motieka & Audzevicˇius Popovici Nitu & Asociatii SJ Berwin Steptoe & Johnson LLP Sullivan & Cromwell LLP Szabó Kelemen & Partners Attorneys Taylor Wessing Vasil Kisil & Partners Vogel & Vogel Wikborg Rein www.globalcompetitionreview.com EU: MONOPOLISATION Post Danmark: predatory pricing in the European Union Howard Rosenblatt, Héctor Armengod and Andreas Scordamaglia-Tousis Latham & Watkins Introduction that a dominant firm can only be interested in applying such low In last year’s edition, we wrote that unilateral pricing behaviour – in prices to eliminate competitors and gain a dominant position which that case, conditional discounts – requires a careful approach to will allow it to exercise market power.6 As the Court explained in enforcement. While under-enforcement could undermine competi- France Télécom, the relevant measure of costs are those of the domi- tion, over-enforcement could deter companies from charging low nant firm, even if they are not below costs incurred by competitors.7 prices – both outcomes that are bad for consumers. The stakes are Nevertheless, this presumption could theoretically be rebutted with equally high in alleged predatory pricing.
    [Show full text]