Historical U.S. Money Growth, Inflation, and Inflation Credibility

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Historical U.S. Money Growth, Inflation, and Inflation Credibility NOVEMBER/DECEMBER1998 William G. Dewald is the retiring Research Director of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Gilberto Espinoza provided research assistance. *Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the Morgan Stanley Dean Witter Interest Rate Conference, Little Rock, Arkansas, May 6, 1998; the Conference on the Conduct of Monetary Policy, Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Taipei, Taiwan, June 12, 1998; and the Institute of Developing Economies, Tokyo, Japan, June 17, 1998. between such nominal variables and real Historical U.S. output. Data from the bond market show that, despite inflation being at its lowest level Money Growth, in decades, the Fed has not regained fully the inflation credibility that it lost in the Inflation, and 1960s and 1970s. Inflation NOMINAL AND REAL Credibility* GROWTH, AND INFLATION The financial press and the public often William G. Dewald seem to believe that the way to contain inflation is to pursue policies that reduce real economic growth. The view that it INTRODUCTION necessarily takes lower real growth, or even a recession, to slow inflation is an lthough many forces affect individual improper reading of historical data. It fails prices in the short run, the historical to differentiate between the short run and Arecord shows that in the long run the long run. Sustained real output growth changes in the general level of prices, i.e., depends on increases in the supply of labor inflation, have been linked systematically and capital, and increases in the productivity to changes in the quantity of money. The of such inputs. Growth in demand for output Federal Reserve uses as its principal mone- certainly influences what is produced, but tary policy target an overnight inter-bank fundamental scarcities limit the aggregate interest rate, the federal funds rate, which amount of how much can be produced on it manipulates by open market operations a sustained basis. Furthermore, as the level that change its portfolio of government and variability of inflation increase, price securities, which in turn influences mone- signals become fuzzier and decisions are tary growth. Economists both inside and distorted, which would tend to decrease real outside the Federal Reserve monitor a wide gross domestic product (GDP). Thus, one range of indicators so as to judge the should not expect an increase in demand appropriateness of a monetary policy target growth to increase real growth on a sustained relative to the goals of achieving a stable basis, but if at all, only in the short run. An price level and sustained real growth. For examination of the historical record many years presidents of the Federal Reserve supports this proposition. 1 With chain-weights, price indexes Bank of St. Louis and many of its economists Figure 1 is a plot of percentage changes and quantity indexes are calcu- have called attention to research showing over 1959-1997 in nominal GDP, real GDP, lated separately for components that long-term growth of monetary aggre- and the GDP price index. The chart includes of GDP and therefore the differ- gates is among the more important of these year-over-year and 10-year moving averages. ence between nominal GDP indicators. They also have championed the The four-quarter changes—the fine lines— and real GDP growth is only preeminence of price level stability as a remove the high frequency noise from the approximately equal to the monetary policy goal to provide the best data. The 10-year changes—the heavy change in the GDP price index. With fixed-weights, the GDP environment for sustained economic growth lines—remove the business cycle fluctua- deflator is defined as the ratio in a market economy. tions as well. The gap between nominal of nominal to real GDP and The historical data reveal a consistent and real GDP growth rates approximates hence the gap between nomi- correlation between long-term growth rates inflation, as measured by percentage changes nal and real GDP growth rates in broad monetary aggregates, spending, in the GDP price index, which are shown is precisely equal to the growth and inflation in the United States, but not in the bottom panel of Figure 1.1 rate in the GDP deflator. FEDERALRESERVEBANKOFST. LOUIS 13 NOVEMBER/DECEMBER1998 Figure 1 Inflation and Real Growth (Year/Year and 10-Year Averages) Percent 25 Nominal GDP 20 15 Real GDP 10 5 0 -5 -10 1959 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 25 20 GDP Inflation 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 1959 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 NOTE: The bold lines are centered 10 year moving averages of the respective series. Figure 1 reveals several regular patterns: the early phase of recoveries. •Inflation trended up through •In recent years inflation has been about 1980, and down its lowest and most stable since since then. the late 1950s and early 1960s, and, atypically, it has continued •Annual growth rates in nominal to decelerate in the seventh year GDP and real GDP went up and of the expansion. down together. The year-over-year movements in nominal •Annual growth rates in nominal and real GDP are matched closely in theshort and real GDP were also more run, an observation seemingly suggesting volatile than annual inflation rates. that policies to increase nominal GDP growth would increase real GDP growth,too. That •Recessions—marked by the short–run relationship, however, does not shaded bars—occurred more hold up in the long run. From the1960s frequently from the late 1960s through the early 1980s the increase in 10-year through the early 1980s when average nominal GDP growth was associated inflation was high and rising with a matching increase in 10-year average than since the early eighties inflation, but, if anything, a decrease in 10-year when it trended down. average real GDP growth.Thus, increased average nominal GDP growthin the long •Inflation typically accelerated run was not associated with increased real before cyclical peaks, but GDP growth, but only with inflation. then decelerated beginning in International evidence supports this recessions and extending into finding that inflation harms long-run growth. FEDERALRESERVEBANKOFST. LOUIS 14 NOVEMBER/DECEMBER1998 Studies of other countries have identified a MONETARY GROWTH small negative effect of even moderate inflation AND INFLATION on real growth.2Small differences amount to a lot over long periods because of com- M2 is a measure of money that Milton pounding. Thus, it may notbe an accident Friedman and Anna Schwartz trace in their of history that the most highly industrialized Monetary History of the United States.4 It is economies with the highest per capita income a broad measure made up of assets having today have had comparatively low inflation a common characteristic: Each is either over extended periods. With respect to coun- issued by the monetary authorities, for triesthat have experienced inflation of 40 example, currency and coin, or is an oblig- percent a year or more,the evidence is ation of a depository institution legally unambiguous: High inflation reduces convertible into such standard monetary real growth.3 units. M2 assets can be divided into M1 High inflation also has been linked to and non-M1 categories. M1 components cyclical instability. There was a deep reces- can be used to make payments directly sion in 1981 and 1982. This recessionwas (currency, travelers checks, and checking associated with a genuinely restrictive mone- accounts). Non-M1 components, which tarypolicy and interest rates at unprecedented can be readily turned into M1 assets, levels. The rate of unemployment built up to include savings deposits, money-market more than 10 percent and inflation fell far mutual fund balances, and short-term time more sharply than most forecasters had deposits. Such non-M1 components of M2 expected. Despite some relapse in the late have become increasingly accessible to 1980s, inflation has trended down sincethe depositors for payments in recent years. early 1980s, and real GDP growth has averaged M2, as a broad monetary aggregate, repre- somewhat less than it did in the 1960s, but sents the essence of “liquidity,” i.e., a way this is because of lower productivity growth station between income receipts and and not because of recessions and unemploy- expenditures for both households and ment.In fact, the U.S. economy has per- non-financial businesses, and, as such, a formed very well relative to its potential and variable that would be expected to be better than ever in termsof cyclical stability. related to total national spending in The 29-quarter expansionfrom 1991:Q1 current dollar terms, i.e., nominal GDP. through 1998:Q2 had not yet lasted as long Figure 2 plots growth rates in M2, nominal as the record 34-quarter expansion of the GDP, and the GDP price index. It reveals some 1960s. However, as inflation decreased from regular short-term patterns in the year- the end of the recessionin 1982:Q4 through over-year data:5 1998:Q2, there were 63 expansion quarters and only three contraction quarters, an • M2 and nominal GDP growth unprecedented era of cyclical stability in rates slow before and during the 2 U.S. history. It surpassedthe record of initial stages of a recession. See Barro (1996) and Eijffinger, Schaling, and 1961:Q1 through 1973:Q4, which included Hoeberichts (1998). 47 positive growth quartersand four con- • M2 growth turned down many traction quarters. The record was not too more times than the number of 3 See Bruno and Easterly shabby in either case, but therewas a differ- cyclical peaks. (1996). ence. The 1960s and early 1970swere a 4 See Friedman and Schwartz period of accelerating inflation, whichlaid a • M2 growth turned up during (1963).
Recommended publications
  • Money in the Economy: a Post-Keynesian Perspective
    Money in the Economy: A post-Keynesian perspective Jo Michell, SOAS, University of London Fundamental Uncertainty • Originates in Keynes’ theory of probability • “non-ergodic” = distinction between known probability distribution (known unknowns) and unknowable future (unknown unknowns) • Risk and uncertainty • Conventions and animal spirits • Decisions on investment and saving “Is our expectation of rain, when we start out for a walk, always more likely than not, or less likely than not, or as likely as not? I am prepared to argue that on some occasions none of these alternatives hold, and that it will be an arbitrary matter to decide for or against the umbrella. If the barometer is high, but the clouds are black, it is not always rational that one should prevail over the other in our minds, or even that we should balance them, though it will be rational to allow caprice to determine us and to waste no time on the debate” (Keynes, Treatise on Probability) Money • Mechanism to cope with uncertainty • Three functions: store of value, unit of account, means of payment • Liquidity • Means to transfer purchasing power in order to meet contractual obligations • Contrast with Classical view: money as a means of transaction. Why hold money? “Money, it is well known, serves two principal purposes. By acting as a money of account it facilitates exchange without its being necessary that it should ever itself come into the picture as a substantive object. In this respect it is a convenience which is devoid of significance or real influence. In the second place, it is a store of wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. Working Paper The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. (2007) : The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/4105 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IZA DP No. 2900 The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties Marika Karanassou Hector Sala Dennis J.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • Weimar Republic Hyperinflation Through a Modern Monetary Theory Lens Phil Armstrong and Warren Mosler 2020 Abstract
    Weimar Republic Hyperinflation through a Modern Monetary Theory Lens Phil Armstrong and Warren Mosler 2020 Abstract The hyperinflation in Weimar Germany in 1922-23 has become the poster child of mainstream economists - and especially the monetarists- when presenting the benefits of constraining governments by the rules of ‘sound finance’. Their narrative presumes that governments are naturally inclined to spend beyond their means and that, if left to their profligate ways, inflation ‘gets out of hand’ and leads to hyperinflation in a continuous, accelerating, unstoppable catastrophic collapse of the value of the money. In contrast to this ubiquitous mainstream analysis, we recognize a fundamentally different origin of inflation, and argue that inflation requires sustained, proactive policy support. And, in the absence of such policies, inflation will rapidly subside. We replace the erroneous mainstream theory with the knowledge of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) identifying both the source of the price level and what makes it change. We are not Weimar scholars, and our aim is not to present a comprehensive historical analysis. We examine the traditionally reported causal forces behind the Weimar hyperinflation, along with the factors that contributed to the hyperinflation and to its abrupt end. The purpose of this paper is to present our view of the reported information from an MMT perspective. In that regard, we identify the cause of the inflation as the German government paying continuously higher prices for its purchases, particularly those of the foreign currencies the Allies demanded for the payment of reparations, and we identify the rise in the quantity of money and the printing of increasing quantities of banknotes as a consequence of the hyperinflation, rather than its cause.
    [Show full text]
  • Answer Key to Problem Set 4 Fall 2011
    Answer Key to Problem Set 4 Fall 2011 Total: 15 points 1(4 points, 1 point for (a) and 0.5 point for each effect ).a. If the Fed reduces the money supply, then the aggregate demand curve shifts down. This result is based on the quantity equation MV = PY, which tells us that a decrease in money M leads to a proportionate decrease in nominal output PY (assuming that velocity V is fixed). For any given price level P, the level of output Y is lower, and for any given Y, P is lower. b. In the short run, we assume that the price level is fixed and that the aggregate supply curve is flat. In the short run, the leftward shift in the aggregate demand curve leads to a movement such that output falls but the price level doesn’t change. In the long run, prices are flexible. As prices fall, the economy returns to full employment. If we assume that velocity is constant, we can quantify the effect of the 5-percent reduction in the money supply. Recall from Chapter 4 that we can express the quantity equation in terms of percentage changes: %∆ +%∆ =%∆ +%∆ If we assume that velocity is constant, then the %∆ =0.Therefore, %∆ =%∆ +%∆ We know that in the short run, the price level is fixed. This implies that the %∆ =0.Therefore, %∆ =%∆ Based on this equation, we conclude that in the short run a 5-percent reduction in the money supply leads to a 5-percent reduction in output. In the long run we know that prices are flexible and the economy returns to its natural rate of output.
    [Show full text]
  • Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation
    Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation: A VAR Perspective∗ Elena Bobeica and Marek Jaroci´nski European Central Bank In the immediate wake of the Great Recession we didn’t see the disinflation that most models predicted and, subse- quently, we didn’t see the inflation they predicted. We show that these puzzles disappear in a vector autoregressive model that properly accounts for domestic and external factors. This model reveals strong spillovers from U.S. to euro-area inflation in the Great Recession. By contrast, domestic factors explain much of the euro-area inflation dynamics during the 2012–14 missing inflation episode. Consequently, euro-area economists and models that excessively focused on the global nature of inflation were liable to miss the contribution of deflationary domestic shocks in this period. JEL Codes: E31, E32, F44. 1. Introduction The dynamics of inflation since the start of the Great Recession has puzzled economists. First, a “missing disinflation” puzzle emerged when inflation in advanced economies failed to fall as much as expected given the depth of the recession (see, e.g., Hall 2011 on the United States and Friedrich 2016 on the rest of the advanced ∗We thank Marta Ba´nbura, Fabio Canova, Matteo Ciccarelli, Luca Dedola, Thorsten Drautzburg, Paul Dudenhefer, Philipp Hartmann, Giorgio Primiceri, Chiara Osbat, Mathias Trabandt, and three anonymous referees for their com- ments. This paper is part of the work of the Low Inflation Task Force of the ECB and the Eurosystem. The opinions in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank and the Eurosys- tem.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Growth, Business Cycles, Unemployment, and Inflation
    Introduction Economic Growth, Business n Macroeconomics is the study of the aggregate economy. Cycles, Unemployment, and n The four central issues are: Inflation q growth q business cycles Chapter 5 q unemployment q inflation. 2 Two Frameworks: The Long Run and Growth the Short Run n Issues of growth are considered in a long-run n Generally the Canadian economy is growing framework. or expanding, at average annual rate of 4 percent over the last 130 years (although about 2.5 – 3.5 percent recently). n Business cycles are generally considered in a short-run framework. n The primary measurement of growth is change in real gross domestic product n Inflation and unemployment fall within both frameworks. (real GDP) – the market value of goods and services stated in the prices of a given year. 3 4 Growth Growth n This average annual growth rate is called the n The growth trend we now take for granted secular growth rate. started at the end of the of the18th century. n Since an economy’s population is increasing, n At about the same time, markets and a useful measure of growth is change in per capita real output. democracies became the primary organizing structures of society. n Per capita real output is real GDP divided by the total population. 5 6 Benefits and Costs of Growth Benefits and Costs of Growth n Per capita economic growth allows everyone n The costs of growth include pollution, in society, on average to have more. resource exhaustion, and destruction of natural habitat. n Growth, or predictions of growth, allows governments to avoid hard questions.
    [Show full text]
  • Preferences Over Inflation and Unemployment: Evidence from Surveys of Happiness Author(S): Rafael Di Tella, Robert J
    American Economic Association Preferences over Inflation and Unemployment: Evidence from Surveys of Happiness Author(s): Rafael Di Tella, Robert J. MacCulloch and Andrew J. Oswald Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 1 (Mar., 2001), pp. 335-341 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2677914 Accessed: 25-11-2019 16:54 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review This content downloaded from 206.253.207.235 on Mon, 25 Nov 2019 16:54:42 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Preferences over Inflation and Unemployment: Evidence from Surveys of Happiness By RAFAEL Di TELLA, ROBERT J. MACCULLOCH, AND ANDREW J. OSWALD* Modem macroeconomics textbooks rest upon see that standard characterizations of the policy the assumption of a social welfare function de- maker's objective function put more weight on fined on inflation, ir, and unemployment, U.1 the costs of inflation than is suggested by our However, no formal evidence for the existence understanding of the effects of inflation; in do- of such a function has been presented in the ing so, they probably reflect political realities literature.2 Although an optimal policy rule can- and the heavy political costs of high inflation" not be chosen unless the parameters of the pre- (Blanchard and Fischer, 1989 pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Is There a Stable Relationship Between Money Supply and Price Level? Arguments on Quantity Theory of Money Hongjie Zhao Business School, University of Aberdeen
    January, 2021 Granite Journal Open call for papers Is There a Stable Relationship between Money Supply and Price Level? Arguments on Quantity Theory of Money Hongjie Zhao Business School, University of Aberdeen A b s t r a c t Inflation rate nowadays is one of the main concerns for governments. Having a low and stable inflation rate is beneficial for the whole economy. Quantity Theory of Money provides a direct explanation about the cause and consequences of inflation rate or price level. It relates money supply to the general price level by using a simple multiply equation, which is popular among economists and government officials. This article tries to summarize the origin of money, development of Quantity Theory of Money, and the counterarguments about this theory. [Ke y w o r d s ] : Money; Inflation; Quantity Theory of Money [to cite] Zhao, Hongjie (2021). " Is There a Stable Relationship between Money Supply and Price Level? Arguments on Quantity Theory of Money " Granite Journal: a Postgraduate Interdisciplinary Journal: Volume 5, Issue 1 pages 13-18 Granite Journal Volume 5, Issue no 1: (13-18) ISSN 2059-3791 © Zhao, January, 2021 Granite Journal INTRODUCTION Money is something that is generally accepted by the public. It can be in any form, like metals, shells, papers, etc. Money is like language in some ways. You have to speak English to someone who can speak and listen to English. Otherwise, the communication is impossible and inefficient. Gestures and expressions can pass on and exchange less information. Without money, the barter system, which uses goods to exchange goods, is the alternative way.
    [Show full text]