The Return to Marx

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Return to Marx Rick Kuhn. Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2007. xv + 332 pp. $60.00, cloth, ISBN 978-0-252-03107-6. Reviewed by Gary Roth Published on H-German (May, 2007) Rick Kuhn's biography of Henryk Grossman man's thesis was by then largely immaterial, since draws attention to a theorist who has always oc‐ few people remembered his book by the late cupied an odd place within the Marxist canon. 1930s. Known exclusively for his contributions to Marxi‐ When Grossman frst published his magnum an economic theory, Henryk Grossman's most in‐ opus, the tendency within the various socialist fluential book, The Law of Accumulation and and communist movements was either to revise Breakdown of the Capitalist System, was pub‐ Marx or ignore his economic theories altogether. lished in Germany on the eve of the 1929 Depres‐ Except among small groups of left communists, sion to widespread reviews but almost no practi‐ centered primarily in the United States around cal influence.[1] Grossman (1881-1950) seemed to Paul Mattick, Grossman's exegesis of Marx found have anticipated the economic collapse and of‐ few supporters. Mattick wrote dozens of articles fered a deeply persuasive explanation of its ongo‐ and reviews about Grossman's thesis but was nev‐ ing persistence and severity. Following Karl Marx, er able to convince any of the more popular left he stressed the inability to extract a sufficient journals to publish a piece about his colleague. mass of surplus labor from the working popula‐ Grossman's core audience at any point in time tion, a matter that became ever more difficult probably numbered in the hundreds, perhaps a with the replacement of labor by technology. He few thousand at most. His readers, in any case, also offered a means to understand why a crisis were members of a rather rarified group, since might not lead automatically to the restoration of his book presupposed a knowledge of the three profitable conditions. Neither inflationary policies volumes of Marx's Capital (1867-94), an uncom‐ nor deficit spending were sufficient on their own mon phenomenon even within the Marxist Left. to prompt a sustained level of economic function‐ Socialists and Social Democrats thought in terms ing that surpassed the pre-crash heights. Only the of the reform of the existing economic system, not world war eventually erased the crisis. That the its collapse. The communist parties, on the other world's economic difficulties confirmed Gross‐ H-Net Reviews hand, were so fxated on the Soviet Union that chic nature of the production process, in which Grossman's ideas were of no consequence to firms habitually over- or undershot existing de‐ them, even though some adherents appreciated mand due to lack of planning within the "free his condemnation of the capitalist economy. The market" context. For Grossman, these explana‐ rise of German fascism, however, reoriented the tions focused on concrete manifestations of crises entire Left from the economy of the Depression to rather than their underlying causes and he the politics of democracy, a transformation which moved the focal point of the debate from the over‐ left Grossman isolated and irrelevant. This fate he production of commodities to the overproduction shared with Marxian economic theory. of capital. This aspect of Marx's theory had never If Grossman's infuence was quite limited, this found resonance within the bourgeois world, as was not the case with his impact on the Marxist Marx's theories of value and surplus value were canon. Prior to Grossman, Rosa Luxemburg was far too abstract to be of much practical use, except the last writer to attempt a breakdown theory. as guideposts for radical social movements. Her effort, some ffteen years earlier, had been Following the Depression, Grossman's ideas based on Volume II of Capital. At the time, virtual‐ remained dormant until interest in Marxian eco‐ ly everyone rejected her thesis, the orthodox be‐ nomic theory revived during the 1960s and 1970s, cause she had revised Marx, inappropriately in when the world's economy unraveled anew. Much their opinion, while the mainstream of the social‐ of his work was republished in Germany, where ist movement hoped for a peaceful transition to a the new Left was more Marxist-inclined than per‐ humanistically-based socialism, an aspiration in haps in any other country. With the subsequent tune with the relative success of the various so‐ decline of the new Left, Grossman's exposition of cialist, labor, and trade union movements. In the the catastrophic aspects of Marx's theory seemed aftermath of the First World War, it was the ultra- out of touch with reality yet again. Some discus‐ Left, such as the Marxists to the left of the Com‐ sion of his ideas can still be found here and there, munist Party, that gave her ideas, as well as her but much of it is highly academic and focused on politics, a new hearing. methodological considerations which are ex‐ Grossman's interpretation of Marx shifted the pressed, as is the habit in the feld of economics, locus of theorizing to the largely ignored Volume with mathematical formulas and without direct III of Capital (1894). In his book and in subse‐ reference to social conditions or the actual econo‐ quent articles, Grossman reframed Marx's theory my. of capitalist development by targeting the domi‐ Much to the credit of Kuhn's biography, Gross‐ nant paradigms of economic thought.[2] He criti‐ man is presented as a complex, talented individu‐ cized theories that posited a fundamental equilib‐ al whose career progressed through marked shifts rium in the economy, an assumption common‐ at different points in his life. Grossman had a place in mainstream economics and common much more varied career than often assumed. His enough within Marxism as well. The Marxist tra‐ book on capitalist breakdown was such a signifi‐ dition, on the other hand, tended towards theo‐ cant achievement that it lends itself to images like ries of disequilibrium, a trait it shared with the those stemming from the twenty-five years Marx emerging feld of liberal economics. Luxemburg, is alleged to have spent in the British Library re‐ for instance, had posited a basic disjuncture be‐ searching and writing Capital, while he was actu‐ tween the economy's ability to produce commodi‐ ally spending considerable time sitting in cafes, ties and the restricted capacity of the population drinking coffee and beer, and talking with to consume. Other theorists pointed to the anar‐ friends. For neither Marx nor Grossman does the 2 H-Net Reviews image quite mesh with reality. While still a stu‐ comments when he wrote to Mattick, in one of his dent, Grossman dedicated himself to labor orga‐ few surviving letters, that the failure of the Ger‐ nizing and the development of a Jewish working- man Communist Party to thwart the fascists was class movement in Poland modeled on the Jewish due to its paltry, inadequate leadership--this a Bund in Russia. The Bundists were socialists and statement about a party that prided itself on its anti-Zionists, but they were also cultural national‐ leadership capabilities. Grossman defended the ists who favored nondiscriminatory policies and Soviet Union against its critics on the Left, includ‐ separate cultural and educational institutions ing Mattick and his colleagues of the Frankfurt within a multicultural state. Two years of engaged School. If he had been a "critical" Stalinist in the political activity culminated in Grossman's sud‐ mid-1930s, all reserve slipped away by the end of den return to graduate school, where he pursued the decade. With the anti-communist hysteria that a law degree. His mentor and post-doctoral re‐ unfolded in the United States in the late 1940s, search supervisor was Carl Grünberg, the future Grossman felt himself in danger of prosecution. founder of the Institute for Social Research (the An offer to join the faculty at the University of Frankfurt School). During the First World War, Leipzig in the newly founded GDR resulted in his Grossman was employed as a statistician, demog‐ 1949 relocation. But he was already an ill man rapher, and economist by the Austrian Ministry of and his death followed at the end of the next year. War. His scholarly pursuits were as much applied Although he had continued to write during the as theoretical. Expelled from Austria after the war years of exile, his level of productivity declined when the socialist-dominated coalition purged the progressively and he never rekindled his research civil service of all non-Austrians, Grossman super‐ program. Except for a few essays and reviews, he vised Poland's newly established census bureau did not follow through on the many aspects of his until political pressure forced his ouster because theoretical work he had hoped to clarify, includ‐ he planned to count the minority populations of ing its empirical verification. the country accurately. He was, however, able to The strongest parts of Kuhn's biography cen‐ secure a university appointment, which he held ter on the earlier aspects of Grossman's career, from 1922-25. When membership in the Polish particularly on his attempts to create a counter‐ Communist Party and repeated arrests led to his part to the Russian Bund within the prewar Aus‐ expulsion from Poland, Grünberg invited him to trian empire. This section of Kuhn's book is also join the Frankfurt School. Grossman's book on the most elaborated, although Kuhn's habit of al‐ capitalist breakdown became the school's most ternating between chronological and episodic well-known and influential publication during the modes of presentation lends a certain confusion early 1930s.
Recommended publications
  • The Discontents of Marxism
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive The discontents of Marxism Freeman, Alan London Metropolitan University 30 December 2007 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/48635/ MPRA Paper No. 48635, posted 27 Jul 2013 14:16 UTC The discontents of Marxism Alan Freeman London Metropolitan University Abstract This is a pre-publication version of a full-length review of Kuhn, R. (2007) Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism. Urbana and U of Illinois. Please cite as Freeman, A. 2008. ‘The Discontents of Marxism’. Debatte, 16 (1), April 2008 pp. 122-131 Keywords: Economics, Marxism, Value Theory, Marxist political economy, Marxist Economics, Kondratieff, Grossman JEL Codes: B14, B31, B51 2008j Grossman Review for MPRA.doc Page 1 of 9 Alan Freeman The discontents of Marxism Review of Kuhn, R. (2007) Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism By Alan Freeman, London Metropolitan University In 1977, volumes 2 and 3 of Capital and Class, journal of the seven-year old Conference of Socialist Economists, carried Pete Burgess’s translation of Henryk Grossman’s 1941 review article Marx, Classical Political Economy and the Problem of Dynamics. Of this Kuhn (p190) justly remarks ‘It was and remains one of the most impressive critiques of the methodological underpinnings of the body of ideas known as economics in most universities and the media’. The second part of this article offers a devastating dissection of the approach known as ‘general equilibrium’, which now dominates not only orthodox but ‘Marxist’ economics. Had the participants in the next thirty years of debate around Marx’s economic theories treated this article with even normal professional diligence, most of what passes for ‘theory’ in this field would probably never have been written.
    [Show full text]
  • Contemporary Left Antisemitism
    “David Hirsh is one of our bravest and most thoughtful scholar-activ- ists. In this excellent book of contemporary history and political argu- ment, he makes an unanswerable case for anti-anti-Semitism.” —Anthony Julius, Professor of Law and the Arts, UCL, and author of Trials of the Diaspora (OUP, 2010) “For more than a decade, David Hirsh has campaigned courageously against the all-too-prevalent demonisation of Israel as the one national- ism in the world that must not only be criticised but ruled altogether illegitimate. This intellectual disgrace arouses not only his indignation but his commitment to gather evidence and to reason about it with care. What he asks of his readers is an equal commitment to plumb how it has happened that, in a world full of criminality and massacre, it is obsessed with the fundamental wrongheadedness of one and only national movement: Zionism.” —Todd Gitlin, Professor of Journalism and Sociology, Columbia University, USA “David Hirsh writes as a sociologist, but much of the material in his fascinating book will be of great interest to people in other disciplines as well, including political philosophers. Having participated in quite a few of the events and debates which he recounts, Hirsh has done a commendable service by deftly highlighting an ugly vein of bigotry that disfigures some substantial portions of the political left in the UK and beyond.” —Matthew H. Kramer FBA, Professor of Legal & Political Philosophy, Cambridge University, UK “A fierce and brilliant rebuttal of one of the Left’s most pertinacious obsessions. What makes David Hirsh the perfect analyst of this disorder is his first-hand knowledge of the ideologies and dogmata that sustain it.” —Howard Jacobson, Novelist and Visiting Professor at New College of Humanities, London, UK “David Hirsh’s new book Contemporary Left Anti-Semitism is an impor- tant contribution to the literature on the longest hatred.
    [Show full text]
  • Kuhn Rick Henryk Grossman and The
    Book Reviews 519 independent. In 1923 the Romanian authorities embarked on an extensive programme of Romanianization. The Romanian language became obligatory in primary and secondary education, and German newspapers were heavily censored. That is why this period was chosen for a deeper analysis of the German-Jewish press and the Jewish theatre. The five most important German-Jewish daily newspapers were the Czernowitzer Allgemeine Zeitung (1903–1940), the Czernowitzer Morgenblatt (1918–1940), Das Volk/Neues Cernowitzer Tageblatt (1918–1923), the Ostju¨dische Zeitung (1919–1937), and the Volkspresse/Vorwa¨rts (1899–1937). They represented the different political and cultural tendencies among the Jewish population: conservative, liberal/assimilatory, Jewish nationalist, Zionist, and socialist. The same tendencies were represented in Czernowitz’s German theatre, which was sponsored mainly by Jews. From 1905 onward, when a new theatre was opened, all kinds of German groups played there, with guest performances by Yiddish groups. But from 1921, the German theatre became the victim of Romanian nationalist and anti-Semitic hostility, two years before the official Romanian cultural policy was launched. Romanian students fre- quently disturbed German performances. At the end December 1921 the Romanian author- ities decreed that theatre performances would henceforward be givenonlyinRomanian.The German theatre moved into an old concert hall, but after two seasons it was forced to close. In his detailed study, the author gives an insight into the unique cultural situation of Bukovina and its Jewish population. His attempt to combine a history of the press and the theatre is new, and daring. The list of all daily newspapers and journals in Bukovina from 1882 to 1940 provided at the end of the book is useful; it shows how important the German-speaking Jewish population was for the culture of the whole region.
    [Show full text]
  • Rick Kuhn Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism
    HIMA 13,3_f4_56-100 8/23/05 3:31 PM Page 57 Rick Kuhn Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism Marxists are ambitious.1 We set out not only to understand the world but, more importantly, to change it. We regard ideas as part of the world and seek to understand and change them too. Marxism, as a set of ideas, has no privileged status in this regard. It, too, can be explained within the framework of historical materialism. For Marxism is not only a theory of the working class’ struggle for its own emancipation. This theory is also the product of that struggle and the efforts of real human beings committed to and involved in it. The history of Marxism can only be grasped in the context of the working class’ victories and defeats. This article uses an historical-materialist framework to explore Henryk Grossman’s2 recovery of Marxist economic theory, its preconditions in Grossman’s own experience and its relationships with the recoveries 1 I am grateful to Sam Pietsch, for his insights and perceptive advice; to Gerda and Kurt Kuhn, Mary Gorman and Alyx Kuhn Gorman who have supported and tolerated my work on Grossman for over a decade; and to Historical Materialism’s two referees, for their valuable comments. My biography of Grossman will be published in 2006 by University of Illinois Press. 2 He generally signed himself ‘Henryk Grossman’. This was how his name appeared in Polish publications and those of his works whose appearance in English he oversaw himself. ‘Henryk Grossmann’ was the most common German rendition of his name and the one used in most of his own publications in German.
    [Show full text]
  • I. Parteien 26 Parteien Methodische Und Sachliche Vorbemerkungen 27
    25 I. Parteien 26 Parteien Methodische und sachliche Vorbemerkungen 27 A. Methodische und sachliche Vorbemerkungen Wer sich im Rahmen einer historischen Studie mit Parteien beschäftigt, muss sich zu- nächst einmal mit der Begrifflichkeit auseinandersetzen. Klarheit ist diesbezüglich insbe- sondere deshalb gefordert, weil der Parteibegriff im 19. Jahrhundert erstens starken Verän- derungen unterlag und zweitens in einen normativen Diskurs eingebettet war, dessen Rep- lizierung es zu vermeiden gilt. Zunächst, in der Ära vor der Entstehung der Massenpar- teien, wurde „Partei“ in einem sehr allgemeinen Sinne verwendet, als ein auf irgendwelche Weise institutionalisierter Meinungsträger im politischen Raum. Er setzte damit zwar sehr wohl einen gewissen diskursiven Rahmen voraus, blieb jedoch bei der Beschreibung des in- stitutionellen Trägers unbestimmt. Eine Partei konnte also durchaus zum Beispiel eine Zei- tung sein, wenn sich diese als selbständiger Meinungsträger einbrachte und nicht nur Sprachrohr einer politischen Organisation war. Am weitesten verbreitet war die Kenn- zeichnung einer bestimmten Fraktion im Parlament als Partei, auch wenn diese in keiner Weise außerparlamentarisch institutionalisiert war. Diese Identifizierung von Partei und Fraktion entsprach dem Charakter der Honoratiorenpolitik: Das Parlament war faktisch der alleinige institutionelle Träger politischer Inhalte, und daher konstituierten die dort handelnden Gruppen die Teile (partes) des politischen Diskurses. Erst mit dem Aufkom- men der Massenparteien wandelte sich der Parteibegriff. Er war zwar durchaus noch auf das politische Handeln in den parlamentarischen Körperschaften bezogen. Gleichzeitig kam ihm nun jedoch eine zweite Dimension zu, indem er ein Segment der als Masse ima- ginierten politischen Gesellschaft bezeichnen sollte. Dieser Sachverhalt gilt für westliche Gesellschaften ebenso wie für den Raum, mit dem wir uns hier beschäftigen.
    [Show full text]
  • Imagereal Capture
    1990] Tax: A Look at Some ofLabor's Changes 307 TAX: A LOOK AT SOME OF LABOR'S CHANGES JOHN PASSANf* 1 INTRODUCfION The period of the Hawke Labor Governments has been one of considerable economic change. That change reflects two basic and interrelated factors.1 First, capital accumulation itself is a continually revolutionising process. Competition forces capitalists to search for new and cheaper ways of producing their products in order to gain an advantage over their rivals. Secondly, the international economic system has been in crisis since the mid-1970s. That crisis can be seen in Australia in the tendency of the rate of profit to decline over the last twenty years or so. The strategy underpinning the Hawke Government's actions, and this is as true of the taxation field as any other area, has been to adopt measures that will facilitate capital accumulation and improve profit rates for Australian based capitalists. This article will examine how some of the tax law changes that have been made have been affected by this strategy, in particular the internationalisation of the Australian economy. In the first place however, these changes have to be seen as part of the more general process ofchange itself. 2 THE PROCESS OF CHANGE IN GENERAL Change continues to sweep the world. The most obvious and inspiring example is Eastern Europe where many of the state capitalist regimes have been overthrown in the last eighteen months or so. In those countries the clash of the forces of production2 with the relations of production3 (in its essentials capitalist4) has produced a move towards the market as a solution to economic problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Henryk Grossman and the History of Science, a Biographical Sketch
    Henryk Grossman and the history of science, a biographical sketch Rick Kuhn Henryk Grossman is best known as an economic theorist. This sketch outlines his life, with an emphasis on his commitment to Marxism, which underpinned not only his contributions to the theory of economic crisis, the labor theory of value, imperialism and Marx’s method in Capital, but also his work in economic history, the history of economic thought and the history of science. It draws on Henryk Grossman and the recovery of Marxism, the full biography of Grossman, and only provides citations to sources not referenced there.1 Chaskel Grossman’s parents, Herz Grossman and Sara Kurz, had an unconventional relationship. Herz was much older than Sara and they had five children between 1876 and 1884, before getting married in 1887. Herz’s business activities were very successful. The family was Jewish, but increasingly assimilated to the Polish high culture of Galician government, big business and art. For the constitutional reform of the Austro-Hungarian Empire in 1867 had given effective local control of its economically backward Polish province and its thoroughly undemocratic parliament to the upper reaches of the Polish nobility. On 14 April 1881, Herz and Sara’s son, Chaskel, was born in Kraków, the administrative capital of western Galicia and the cultural capital of partitioned Poland. Chaskel is a Yiddish name, but he was probably known, like his father, as Henryk from an early age, and formally adopted this Polish name in early 1915. Henryk and his surviving brother went to a twelve year, academic high school.
    [Show full text]
  • Jewish Anti-Zionism in the Galician Socialist Movement1
    R ICK K UHN Jewish Anti-Zionism in the Galician Socialist Movement 1 Galicia, the Polish province of the Austro-Hungarian empire, was one of its most economically backward regions. Despite Jews’ over-representation in urban areas, only ten percent of the small manual working class in Galicia was Jewish, roughly the proportion of Jews in the overall population of 7,136,000 in 1900. 2 Although formally emancipated in 1867, Austrian Jews and especially those in the eastern provinces of the Empire, the overwhelming majority of whom spoke Yiddish as their first language, remained an oppressed group. They suffered from entrenched, if often unofficial, discriminatory practices and at - titudes. They were also subject to formal, legal discrimination. Under laws which dated back to the late 18th century, as well as more recent legislation and ordinances, Yiddish was not accorded the same status in the courts, with public authorities or in the education system as officially recognised languages. 3 There were Jewish workers amongst the earliest members of the social demo cratic (Marxist) movement in Galicia, in the early 1890s. By 1896 there were general workers’ associations in Kraków, Lemberg (now L’viv in Ukraine), Kolomea (Kolomya in Ukraine) and Przemyśl. 4 A territorial social democratic 1 This paper derives the larger project which gave rise to Rick Kuhn’s Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism, University of Illinois Press, Urbana and Chicago 2007. 2 J. Thon, “Die Berufsgliederung der Juden in Galizien,” Zeitschrift für Demographie und Statistik der Juden , 3 (8-9), August-September 1907, pp. 114-116.
    [Show full text]
  • Roth on Kuhn, 'Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism'
    H-German Roth on Kuhn, 'Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism' Review published on Tuesday, May 1, 2007 Rick Kuhn. Henryk Grossman and the Recovery of Marxism. Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 2007. xv + 332 pp. $25.00 (paper), ISBN 978-0-252-07352-6; $60.00 (cloth), ISBN 978-0-252-03107-6. Reviewed by Gary Roth (Rutgers University at Newark) Published on H-German (May, 2007) The Return to Marx Rick Kuhn's biography of Henryk Grossman draws attention to a theorist who has always occupied an odd place within the Marxist canon. Known exclusively for his contributions to Marxian economic theory, Henryk Grossman's most influential book, The Law of Accumulation and Breakdown of the Capitalist System, was published in Germany on the eve of the 1929 Depression to widespread reviews but almost no practical influence.[1] Grossman (1881-1950) seemed to have anticipated the economic collapse and offered a deeply persuasive explanation of its ongoing persistence and severity. Following Karl Marx, he stressed the inability to extract a sufficient mass of surplus labor from the working population, a matter that became ever more difficult with the replacement of labor by technology. He also offered a means to understand why a crisis might not lead automatically to the restoration of profitable conditions. Neither inflationary policies nor deficit spending were sufficient on their own to prompt a sustained level of economic functioning that surpassed the pre-crash heights. Only the world war eventually erased the crisis. That the world's economic difficulties confirmed Grossman's thesis was by then largely immaterial, since few people remembered his book by the late 1930s.
    [Show full text]
  • The Free Machine
    REVIEWS Paul Mason, Postcapitalism: A Guide To Our Future Allen Lane: London 2015, £16.99, hardback 340 pp, 978 1 846 14738 8 Rob Lucas THE FREE MACHINE Paul Mason’s Postcapitalism is an ambitious book, spanning economic his- tory and theory, the trajectory of socialism, diagnosis of the crisis-prone present and a strategic vision for the future. It is also an unusual one, treat- ing topics typically ceded to left antiquarians with a free spirit that aims to build a grandiose historical-theoretical construction out of insights from Mises and Marx, Luxemburg and Hayek, Preobrazhensky and Gorz. And a best-seller—a notable feat for a work that covers such ground; due in part, perhaps, to Mason’s high visibility as economics editor at the bbc and Channel 4. Born in Lancashire in 1960, the son of a lorry driver and a primary school headmistress, Mason claims to have become ‘a Marxist at 16, a Trotskyist at 19’. He studied music and politics at Sheffield, starting an academic career in music in the early 1980s before switching to jour- nalism. By the time of the late-90s dot.com bubble he was deputy editor of Computer Weekly, then joined bbc Newsnight as business editor, his first broadcast discussing the economic fallout of the 11 September attacks. In 2013 he moved to Channel 4. In these posts he has become a household name in Britain, known for his ruffled pieces-to-camera from the frontline of global uprisings. But he has straddled the range of media from tv and radio to newspaper columns, blogs, with a prominent Twitter and Facebook presence, and a novel set in China’s Wild West.
    [Show full text]
  • PROFITABILITY and ECONOMIC CRISIS Rick Kuhn and Tom O'lincoln
    PROFITABILITY AND ECONOMIC CRISIS Rick Kuhn and Tom O'Lincoln During the early and mid-1970s, an analysis of capitalist economic crisis which located its causes in the heart of the relations of production had some currency in Australia ( e.g.Vort-Roland,1974:6-13; Brezniak and Collins, 1977:7-16; Rowley, 1976:37-39; Silver, 1977:54-62.) This ap­ proach drew on Marx's account of the tendency for the rate of profit to fall. Overseas, some Marxists have continued to analyse developments in terms of the rate of profit. In Australia, however, such theories have fallen out of fashion. Recent discussions of the problems of the domestic economy by radical economists have made no mention of it. 1 Ironically, this neglect by mdical theorists comes at a time when much improved statistical sources have begun to provide very useful data on profit rates, and there is increasing interest in the subject by economists pursuing the interests of business and involved in government policy making. We use the term 'crisis' to refer to an outstanding feature of world capitalism over the past decade and a half. The crisis is the period of prolonged relative stagnation since the early 1970s, rather than a sharp rupture or turning point. Different explanations of the economic crisis can have radically different implications for political action. The following discussion seeks to establish the relevance of the approach which focuses on the theory of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall. The opening section surveys recent overseas evidence on profit rates and offers a theoretical account of the tendency for profit rates to fall.
    [Show full text]
  • Marx, Classical Political Economy and the Problem of Dynamics Part I
    ARCHIVE : MARX, CLASSICAL POLITICAL ECONOMY AND THE PROBLEM OF DYNAMICS PART I Henryk Grossman Translated by Pete Burgess I The dominant view of Marx is to regard him as a student of and successor to the Classical economists ; as an economist who 'completed' that work .(1) The result is a precisely formulated conception : the labour theory of value, as expounded by Smith and Ricardo, in essence leads on to socialism - a consequence left unstated by the theory's founders . Marx was the first to think Ricardo's theory through to its conclusion, completing the latter's final unstated words, as it were. (21 However, this interpretation begins to look extremely question- able when it is viewed from the vantage point provided by the crtique of political economy, which posits that 'the development of political economy and of the opposition to which it gives rise keeps pace with thereat development of the social contradictions and class conflicts inherent in capitalist production' .(3J Marx distinguishes four phases in the development of political economy : the first embraces the period of 'Classical political economy', and the remaining three the various stages of 'Vulgar Economics'. For Marx, the factor which unites the representatives of Classical political economy into one intellectual school is the basic similarity of their historical situation, despite their sometimes great individual differences, e .g. between Petty, Hume and the Physiocrats, and between the latter and Smith or Ricardo .(4J This period was that of the coming into being of modern capitalism, hence the modern working class, and consequently a time in which the 'class struggle .
    [Show full text]