A Framework for the Analysis of

SHAUN D. LEDGERWOOD AND PAUL R. CARPENTER * The Brattle Group

Market manipulation is a poorly understood phenomenon, due in part to legal standards that categorizemanipulativebehavioraseitheranactofoutrightfraudorasthenebuloususeofmarket powertoproduceanartificialprice.Inthispaper,weconsiderathirdtypeofbehaviorthatcantrigger amanipulation–uneconomictrading.Wedemonstratethatuneconomictradinghascharacteristicsof bothfraudandmarketpower,thusprovidingafoundationforanalyzingmanipulativebehaviorina manner consistent across “fraudbased” and “artificial price” statutes. We develop an analytical framework to assist this process that describes pricebased manipulation as an intentional act (the “trigger”) made to cause a directional price movement (the “nexus”) to benefit financially leveraged positionsthattietothatprice(the“target”).Thisframeworkcouldsimultaneouslyimprovemarket liquidityandcompliancebyprovidingdefinitionalandanalyticcertaintyconcerningwhatbehaviordoes anddoesnotconstituteamarketmanipulation.

1. INTRODUCTION PassageoftheDoddFrankWallStreetReformandConsumerProtectionAct(P.L. No:111203[July21,2010])(hereafterDoddFrank)alteredseveralstatutory provisions relevant to the proof of intent in market manipulation cases, includingtheadditionofafraudprovisiontotheantimanipulationlanguageof theCommodityExchangeAct(CEA)(7U.S.C.§§1etseq.[2010]).Advocates

*Theauthors’commentsaretheirownanddonotnecessarilyrepresentthoseofothersat TheBrattleGroup.TheauthorswishtothanktheReviewersoftheReviewofLawandEconomicsfor their exceptional comments, which greatly improved this paper. Thanks also to Dan Arthur, Romkaew Broehm, Peter FoxPenner, Dan Gaynor, Oliver Grawe, Dan Harris, M. Alexis Maniatis,JanuszMrozek,HannesPfeifenberger,JimReitzes,JohnSimpson,andGaryTaylor ofTheBrattleGroup.SpecialthankstoDr.TimothyBrennanoftheUniversityofMaryland, Dr.MichaelGoldsteinofBabsonCollege,Dr.AndrewKleitofPennStateUniversity,Dr.PetruS. Stoianovici,andtoMatthewL.Hunterfortheircommentsonthistopic.

DOI: 10.1515/1555-5879.1577

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 254 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 for this change included Bart Chilton, Commissioner of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), who stated that “…in 35 years, there hasbeenonlyonesuccessfulprosecutionformanipulation”bytheCFTC.1In disagreement,anotedauthorarguedthatafraudbasedstandardforproofof manipulative intent will complicate future cases under the CEA because the triggering mechanism for many manipulations is market power, not fraud (Pirrong, 2010). This perspective has an intuitive appeal. Economic theory instructs that the ability of a market participant to unilaterally move prices requires that it wields and uses market power, an act of flexing economic muscles,notofdeceptionordeceit.Withoutsuchpower,theparticipantisleft toinduceotherstocausethedesiredpricemovement,asmightoccurfromthe introductionoffalseormisleadinginformationintothemarket.Iftheuniverse ofactionsthatmaytriggerapricebasedmanipulationislimitedtothemutually exclusive categories of behavior associated with the creation of an “artificial price”(byusingmarketpower)orthroughtheuseofoutrightfraud,theneed fordualantimanipulationprovisionswithinDoddFrankseemscogent. However,thisviewpointisincomplete.Whileitiscertainlytruethatmarket power and outright fraud are means by which to cause a directional price movement,thereisathirdtypeofbehaviorthatisoddlyunderstudiedinthe literature and which intersects both of these categories: uneconomic trading. Specifically,amanipulatorneedsnomarketpowerinanytraditionalsenseto directionallymoveapriceinoppositiontoitsstandaloneselfinterest.Because othermarketparticipantsassume(bytheselfinteresthypothesis)thatallbids areplacedatorbelowabuyer’struewillingnesstopayandthatalloffersare placed at or above a seller’s marginal costs, there is a presumption that executionofthosebidsoroffersmaximizesthewelfareoftheirsponsorsona standalonebasis,thusprovidingmeaningfulinformationastothevalueofthe underlyingassettraded(Hellwig,1980).Thisisalsocongruentwithatraditional viewofmarketpower,wherebuyersandsellersbenefitonastandalonebasis fromhigherandlowerprices,respectively,butareconstrainedbycompetitive forces. Compare this to a situation where a trader places a bid or offer at a price specifically designed to lose money on a standalone basis (e.g., a bid above the trader’s willingness to pay or a sale below marginal cost). Increasingly uneconomic bids or offers will face diminishing competition, makingtheirexecutionincreasinglylikely.Theabilitytopostsuchtradesisnot

1 Commissioner Chilton’s remarks were made on March 23, 2010, to the Metals Market groupinWashington,D.C.The“onesuccessfulprosecution”referredtoisDiPlacidov. CFTC,anenergytradingcasedecidedinOctober,2009.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 255 afunctionofmarketpower,butratherofthewillingnessoftheproponentto absorblossesonastandalonebasis.2 Concernsaboutuneconomictradingareheightenedifthetradesare“price making,”suchasthroughcontributionstotheformationandpublicationofa price index. If so, parties with small market shares can cause relatively large directionalpricemovementsbyplacinguneconomictradesstrategicallysoasto maximize their directional impact on the published price index and benefit financiallyleveragedpricetakingpositionsthattietothatindex.3Thereliance ontraditionaleconomictoolstounravelandexplainthecounterintuitivelogic ofsuchlossseekingbehaviormayunderliewhysofewsuccessfulenforcement actionsexistforwhatAllenandGale(1992)termed“tradebasedmanipulation” undertheexistingantimanipulationstatutes.Thedearthofcasesshouldnot necessarilybeattributedtoshortcomingsofcurrentantimanipulationlaws,for uneconomicbehaviorsimultaneouslyinjectsfalseinformationintothemarket andcontributestoanartificialprice.Amoreplausibleexplanationisthatthe absence of a cohesive economic framework to generally explain pricebased market manipulationhas dampened the analytical processfor “distinguishing an illegal scheme from a legal one which might manifest itself in identical behavior, differing only perhaps in private information in the mind of the perpetrator” (Kyle and Viswanathan, 2008). This void perpetuates uncertainty for marketparticipantsseekingclarityastothebehaviorthatwillandwillnotbe deemed manipulative, and it frustrates compliance by failing to provide the marketandregulatorswithmeaningfulguidance.

2Manylegitimatereasonsmightunderlieatrader’swillingnesstoincurlossesonspecific transactions,rangingfromstupiditytotheneedforimmediateliquidation(orprocurement)of the asset traded. However, the trader’s willingness to incur such losses on a repeated or anomalousbasisbringsintoquestionwhetherthemotivationforthebehaviorwaslegitimate onastandalonebasis.Aswediscuss,onepurposeofthemanipulationframeworkwepresent istodescribeandhelpidentifybehaviorthatcouldgiverisetolossbasedopportunism.This behavior is often confused for traditional market power, especially on the buyer side. For exampleswhereconcernsaboutuneconomicentryhaveledtothemitigationofbuyermarket power in electricity capacity markets, see Order on Proposed Revisions to InCity BuyerSide MitigationMeasures,133FERC¶61,178(2010);OrderAcceptingProposedTariffRevisionsSubjectto Conditions, and Addressing Related Complaint, 135 FERC ¶61,022 (2011); and Order on Paper HearingandOrderonRehearing,135FERC¶61,029(2011),note57. 3ThefocusofDoddFrankisto monitortheaccumulationoffinancialderivativesasprice taking instruments that could enable crossmarket manipulations triggered by pricemaking trades that set the value of underlying physical assets. However, it is possible that the price makingandpricetakingassetscoexistinthesamemarket,aswouldoccurifpricemakingsales thatsetanindexvalueweremadeoutofaphysicalpurchased“atindex”(i.e.,ata pricethatistakenfromthevalueatwhichthatsameindexultimatelyresolves).

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 256 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

In this paper, we propose and discuss a generalized economic framework (“theframework”)fortheanalysisofpricebasedmarketmanipulation,whether the manipulation is triggered by uneconomic trades, outright fraud, or the exerciseofmarketpower.Muchofouranalysiscentersonuneconomictrading, foritistheleastobviousofthethreephenomenaandfillsthegapbetweenthe statutes explicitly designed to prevent the other two types of behavior. Uneconomictradinghasalsoprovidedthebasisforseveralenforcementactions broughtbytheagenciesempoweredwithantimanipulationauthority.Therefore, we begin by constructing the framework around a definition of lossbased manipulative behavior: intentionally losing money on anomalous pricemaking trades to benefit the value of the trader’s related pricetaking positions, where lossesaremeasuredrelative tothetrader’sopportunitycosts4 (Ledgerwood, 2010; Ledgerwood et al., 2011; Ledgerwood and Harris, 2012; Ledgerwood and Pfeifenberger, 2012). Themanipulationconsistsofthreecomponents:  The “Trigger”: The pricemaking trades used to inject false information into the market as to the value of the asset traded and to thus cause a directionalpricemovement;  The “Target”: The pricetaking positions held by the trader that will benefitfromthedirectionalpricemovementcausedbythetrigger;and  The“Nexus”:Thelinkagebetweenthetriggerandtarget–inthiscase,the pricethatisdirectionallymovedtoexecutethepricebasedmanipulation. By separating the analysis of a manipulation into these three elements, the framework characterizes a trader’s decision to use uneconomic trades for manipulationasacostbenefitanalysis,wherelossesinthetriggerareviewed relativetothebenefitsderivedinthetarget.Thisholdsfouradvantages.First, itprovidescertaintyastothetypesofbehaviorthatarenotmanipulative,suchas the financially unleveraged hedging of positional risk. Second, since uneconomic trading simultaneously injects false price information into the

4Uneconomictradingmaybeprofitableonanaccountingbasis,butforegoanopportunityto make more money in an alternative trade. For example, see the case of the soybean trader described by Pirrong (2010:1718) and the case of manipulating financial transmission rights usingvirtualtransactionsdiscussedbyLedgerwoodandPfeifenberger(2012).Apartyassertinga marketmanipulationclaimthereforefacesadifficultburdenofestablishingthatthetrader(1) recognizedthatsuchopportunitiesexisted,yet(2)intentionallychosenottopursuethem.Itis forthisreasonthatweincludeinourdefinitionarequirementthatthepricemakingtradesbe showntobesufficientlyanomaloussoastodistinguishthemfromlegitimatebehavior.Though atfirstblushthismightseemtobereplacingonevaguestandardwithanother,wediscussinthis paper some possible methods for screening for such behavior using methodologies already describedintheliteratureconcerningpricesupportstrategies.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 257 marketastothevalueoftheassettradedandcontributestotheformationof an artificial price, the framework provides equivalent analyses of pricebased manipulationsunderfraudbasedstatutesortheartificialpricestandardofthe CEA.5Third,separateanalysisofthecausaltriggeralsomakestheframework “portable” for analyzing other types of pricebased manipulations, including thosetriggeredbyoutrightfraud(whicharecostlesstothemanipulator)and actual market power (which profit the manipulator on a standalone basis).6 Finally,thelogicalconstructoftheframework’scomponentsdemonstratesthat the success of tradebased manipulations ultimately depends on a few key characteristics that must exist in a market’s microstructure to allow such misinformationtoproduceitsdesiredeffect(O’Hara,1995).Wediscusseachof theseadvantagesingreaterdetailinthesectionsthatfollow. Theremainderofthisarticleconsistsoffoursections.Section2presentsthe frameworkwithinthecontextoftheexistingstatutes,caselaw,andliterature thatpertaintopricebasedmarketmanipulation.Section3providesanexample of an indexbased market manipulation, demonstrating that a market participant with insignificant market share can effectively trigger a manipulationusinguneconomictrades.Thepresentationisthengeneralizedto aclearedmarkettocharacterizethemanipulator’sprofitmaximizingdecision and to verify the market conditions that favor manipulation. Section 4 discussestheinefficiencyandharmcausedbymanipulationandpositsscreens foritsdetection.Section5concludes.

2. THE FRAMEWORK IN THE CONTEXT OF MANIPULATION STATUTES, CASE LAW AND THE LITERATURE Recent legislation, regulation, litigation, and scholarship concerning market manipulationgenerallysupportthecharacterizationofmanipulativebehavioras eitherfraudbasedortradebased,withthelattertypicallyascribedtoresultfrom theexerciseofsomevariantoftraditionalmarketpower.However,theCFTC’s historical difficulty in bringing enforcement actions under the artificial price

5 TheproofofanactualmanipulationundertheCEA’sartificialpricestandardrequiresthe demonstration that the accused trader intentionally caused an artificial price to exist. By comparison,theproofofanactualmanipulationunderfraudbasedstatutes(orofanattempted manipulation under the CEA) does not require the showing of an artificial price. For further discussion,seeTable1. 6 Thelogicoftheframeworkcouldalsobeappliedmoregenerallytoexplainawiderarrayof behavior, including, for example, predatory pricing (Ledgerwood and Heath, 2012). To maintain focusontheissueofpricebasedmanipulation,wedonotaddresssuchalternativeapplicationshere.

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 258 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 provisionsoftheCEA,combinedwithhighlydivergentandsometimeshostile viewstowardtradebasedmanipulationexpressedintheacademicliterature,has prompted the U.S. agencies with antimanipulation mandates to request and receivefraudbasedmanipulationstatutesbasedontheSecuritiesandExchange Commission’s (SEC’s) Rule 10b5.7 Now with equivalent rules, enforcement actions by the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), Federal Energy Regulatory Commission(FERC),SEC,and(post–DoddFrank)CFTCcanrelyoncommon caseprecedent,butwithoutthebenefitofacommoneconomicfoundation. Here lies the reasoning of using uneconomic transactions as the initial structure for our proposed framework. If placing trades at prices that are intentionallydesignedtolosemoneypurposefullymisrepresentsthetruevalue oftheexchangedasset,theactisatypeoftransactionalfraudthatfitswithinboth of the traditional definitions of manipulative behavior. This is because the fraud creates the “artificial” directional price movement that benefits the manipulator’s targeted position(s). The framework therefore provides an analytically flexible tool – consistent across statutes, case law, and the economicliteratureonpoint–todescribelossbasedmanipulations.Oncethe framework is in place for explaining uneconomic trading, extending the frameworktoothertypesoftriggersbecomesconceptuallyobvious.

2.1. THE FRAMEWORK AND EXISTING ANTI-MANIPULATION STATUTES Statutorydefinitionsofmarketmanipulationconformtoanddefinethetwo traditionalcategoriesofmanipulativebehavior.Section6(c)oftheCEA,as amended by DoddFrank, prohibits actions that create an artificial price.8 Thisstandardrequiresprovingthemanipulator’s(1)abilityand(2)intentto causeanartificialprice,(3)thatanartificialpricewasinfactcreated,and(4) that, in fact, the manipulator’s actions caused the artificial price.9 By comparison, the prototypical statutory prohibition against fraudbased manipulation is the SEC’s Rule 10b5, which prohibits (1) the use of a fraudulentdevice,scheme,orstatement(2)inconnectionwiththesaleor purchase of a (3) with the requisite scienter (intent). The anti manipulationrulesoftheFERCandtheFTCderivefromtheSEC’sRule 10b5,10 as does the new antimanipulation provision of the CEA post–

7 17C.F.R.§ 240.10b5.Rule10b5arisesundertheauthoritygrantedin15U.S.C.§ 78j(b)(2010). 8 Fordiscussion,seeProhibitionontheEmployment,orAttemptedEmployment,ofManipulative andDeceptiveDevicesProhibitiononPriceManipulation,17C.F.R.Part180(August15,2011) (“CFTCManipulationRule”). 9 SeeId.,at6766067661. 10 TheFERC’santimanipulationruleiscodifiedin18C.F.R.§ 1c(2010),asenabledbythe Energy Policy Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 10958, 119 Stat. 594 et seq. (2005), amending the

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 259

DoddFrank.11 The CFTC’s original standard is retained and explicitly expandedtoprohibitattemptstocreateanartificialprice.12TheEuropean Union has also adopted dual antimanipulation rules, most recently for wholesaleelectricityandnaturalgasmarkets13(LedgerwoodandHarris,2012:1018). The framework reconciles and clarifies how the elements of proof relate under the fraudbased and artificialprice standards. Table 1 presents this conceptually. The rows contain the elements of proof required under the original artificial price standard of the CEA. The columns compare these elementsacrossthethreetypesofantimanipulationrulesthatareinplaceat theCFTC:thefraudbasedstandard,anattemptedartificialpricestandard,and the original artificial price standard of the CEA. The information in parentheses conceptually relates these to the framework by components, as definedforalossbasedmanipulation.

Table 1: The Elements of Proof under Fraud-Based and Artificial Price Standards Fraud-Based Standard Artificial Price Standard Artificial Price Standard Element of Proof (SEC, FTC, FERC, CFTC) (Attempt) (Original) Required Required Required Intent (Scienter) (Loss in Trigger) (Loss in Trigger) (Loss in Trigger) Ability Required Required Required (Device/Scheme) (Leverage in Target) (Leverage in Target) (Leverage in Target) Causation Required Required Required (Device/Scheme) (Nexus) (Nexus) (Nexus) Required Artificial Price Not Required Not Required (Nexus Impact on Target)

Demonstration of the manipulation’s trigger requires proof of intentional uneconomictrading,suchasthroughapatternoflossesanomalouslyincurredby a trader relative to its opportunity costs. Identifying the manipulation’s targets thenshowsthatthetraderhadtheabilitytorecoupitslossesincurredfromthe

FederalPowerAct,15U.S.C.§717c1andtheNaturalGasAct,16U.S.C.§824v(a).TheFTC’s antimanipulationruleiscodifiedin16C.F.R.Part317,asenabledbySection811ofSubtitleB ofTitleVIIIofTheEnergyIndependenceandSecurityActof2007,42U.S.C.1730117305. 11 Thisiscodifiedasanewprovision6(c)(1)intheCEA.SeeCFTCManipulationRule,17C.F.R. Part180.1. 12 Thisiscodifiedasanewprovision6(c)(3)intheCEA.SeeId.,17C.F.R.Part180.2. 13SeeDirective2003/6/ECoftheEuropeanParliamentandoftheCouncilof28January2003on insiderdealingandmarketmanipulation(marketabuse),OJL96,12.4.2003(2006)(MAD);Council Regulation(EU)No1227/2011, OnWholesale EnergyMarketIntegrityandTransparency,at art.2(4)(a),2011OJL326,1.

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 260 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 triggerthroughproofofpricetakingpositionsthataresufficientlyleveragedto more than recoup such losses financially. Proof of causation derives from demonstratingthenexusbetweenthetriggeringlossesandthetargetedpositions. Finally,theproofofanartificialpricederivesfrommeasuringthetrader’simpact onthenexusandresultinggaininthetargetedmarkets,oftencalculatedrelative toa“butfor”competitivepriceassociatedwiththetrader’sopportunitycosts. The framework thus provides a way that is logically and methodologically consistentacrossbothtypesofantimanipulationstatutestofunctionallyseparate theanalysisofamanipulation’scauseandeffect. Whileconceptuallyhelpful,therealitiesofprovingmanipulativebehaviorare less clean than this presentation suggests, as compartmentalization of the analyses does not circumvent the pragmatic difficulties that can arise in real worlddata.Theproofofmanipulativeintentusingtradingdataisaparticularly thorny issue, ultimately requiring a subjective determination that enough circumstantialevidenceoflossesincurredinthetriggerwarrantsafindingof manipulation. Difficulties arise because many assertions of seemingly uneconomical behavior could be rationalized in the context of different informationsets,suchthatatradercanalwaysattempttoexplainitsbehavior aseconomicallyrationalwhenviewedthroughtheappropriatelens.Whilethis can be addressed byshowing that the manipulatorrepeatedly and knowingly ignored its opportunity costs, it presumes that the trader knew of such opportunities at the times when the trades were made. Without more dispositive evidence of intent (such as emails, voice recordings or whistleblowertestimony),proofofthemanipulativetriggerusingtradingdata alone may present a very difficult challenge. In Section 4 we discuss further howananalystmightapproachthisproblem. Other elements of the framework may also present standalone analytical problems. It is possible that some of the positions that are targeted by the manipulation are unobservable, as might occur with derivatives positions acquired off market. For observable positions, the benefit derived may be unquantifiable if, for example, the manipulation benefits some qualitative factorsuchasreputation(Lewellen,2006).Thelackofastableanddemonstrable nexuspresentsasimilarproblem,foranunstablecorrelationwillnotsupporta causallinkbetweenthetriggerandtarget.Finally,theproofofanartificialprice canbeacomplexeffortrequiringtailoredeconometricanalysestodeterminea “butfor”competitivepriceagainstwhichtheartificialpriceismeasured.The difficultyofbringingsuccessfulenforcementactionsundertheCEA’sartificial price standard explains, in part, why the FTC, FERC and CFTC sought legislationfornewmanipulationrulesbasedontheSEC’sRule10b5.These rulesavoidtheneedtoproveartificialpriceasamaterialelementofananti

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 261 manipulation enforcement action, thus easing the proof required to demonstrateamanipulationwithattendantcivilpenaltiesupto$1millionper incidentperday.14Notethatfraudbasedrulesdonoteliminatetheneedfor demonstratingtheeffectoftheartificialprice,becausetheproofofdamagesin civil litigation or of disgorgement in enforcement actions still requires measurementofthepricedistortioncausedbythemanipulation.15 Notwithstanding these difficulties, the framework provides a structure that simplifies the description of what a manipulation is and assists the developmentofanalysestoexplainitskeycomponents.Moreover,theproof ofonecomponentiscomplementarytotheproofoftheothers.Forexample, proofofopportunitybasedlossesinthetradesthattriggerthemanipulationis essentialtoshowing intent(scienter),16 but is also germane to demonstrating ability,causation,andthecreationofanartificialprice.Showingabilityrequires proof of the targeted positions that would profit from the price movement causedbythetrigger,butlikewisesupportstheshowingofmanipulativeintent and causation. Proof of the nexus is essential to showing both ability and causation, which are logically relevant only in the presence of the requisite intent.Finally,proofofanartificialpriceaddsweighttotheentireanalysisby showingandquantifyingademonstrableeffect.Thus,asweturnourattention latertowaystoovercomethepracticalchallengesraisedabove,weassertthat the ultimate value of these analytical processes is measured by the synergies theycreatewhencombined,astheframeworkseekstodo.Thisisequallytrue for the analysis of manipulations that are triggered through the exercise of marketpowerorbyoutrightfraud.

2.2. THE FRAMEWORK AND EXISTING CASE LAW Theframeworkweproposeisconsistentwiththecausationusedbythetriers offactacrosstheregulatoryproceedingsandcourtcasesthathaveevaluated bothlossandfraudbasedmanipulations.Thisisbecausetheanalysesofthe manipulationsassertedinthesecasesallusedreasoninganalogoustoisolating themanipulativetriggerfromitstargetsandbyexplainingthenexuslinkingthe two.SeveralrecentcasesbeforetheFERC,CFTC,SEC,andU.S.Department ofJusticeprovideexamplesofthis.

14 Forexample,see42U.S.C.§17304(FTC);15U.S.C.§717t1(a)and16U.S.C.§825o1(b) (FERC);and7U.S.C.13(a)(2)(CFTC). 15 NotethataprivatecauseofactionisnotallowedundertheFERC’sRule1c. 16 Subtle differences may exist across agencies. For example, the FTC has interpreted the scienter standard under its rule as requiring “extreme recklessness.” SeeProhibitionsonMarket Manipulation; Final Rule, 16 C.F.R. Part 317 (August 12, 2009). By comparison, the CFTC’s standardrequiresonly“recklessness.”

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 262 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

2.2.1. LLC (Amaranth) Amaranth was a fund highly invested in speculative positions in New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX) monthly naturalgas futures contracts and associated lookalike swaps traded on the InterContinental Exchange (ICE)andNYMEXClearPort.LedbytraderBrianHunter,theenergytrading wing of Amaranth attempted an “experiment” beginning in February, 2006. This involved buying a large number of futures contracts at relatively high pricesbeforethesettlementperiodfortheMarchcontract,thensellingthese contractsbacktothemarketinopenoutcrytradingduringthe(pricesetting) 30minute settlement period. On a standalone basis, this behavior was uneconomicbecauseHunterwillinglylostmoneyonthecontractspurchasedat relativelyhighpricesbeforethesettlementperiodandsubsequentlyliquidated those contracts at a lower price during the settlement window. Further, Hunter’sbehaviorwasfoundtobefraudulentbecausehisliquidationthrough the open outcry process was designed to induce othertraders to further the downward pricing by selling for fear of a price collapse. Subsequent analysis revealed that Amaranth had accumulated substantial financialleverageinswapandoptionspositionsthatwere(pricetaking) tothesettlementpriceoftheMarchcontractandthusbenefittedsignificantly fromthelossesinAmaranth’spricemakingtrades.Thisbehaviorwasrepeated fortheApril,2006andMay,2006contracts,drawingenforcementactionsby theFERCandtheCFTC.17 Hunter’s behavior is a quintessential example of a market manipulation as definedbytheframeworkwepropose.AsstatedbytheFERCAdministrative Law Judge in finding guilt, Hunter was found to have executed trades “specificallydesignedtolowertheNYMEXpriceinordertobenefithisswap positionsonotherexchanges”inviolationofRule1c.18Thesalesduringthe settlementlostmoneyonastandalonebasisandwereexecutedinamanner designedtomisleadothertraderstosellintothedipandcarrythepricelower, thus representing two types of manipulative triggers within the same framework.Thetradeswerethusexecutedwithnolegitimatebusinesspurpose

17AmaranthAdvisorsL.L.C.,OrdertoShowCauseandNoticeofProposedPenalties,120FERC¶ 61,085, (July26,2007),andUnitedStatesCommodityFuturesTradingCommissionv.AmaranthAdvisors,L.L.C., AmaranthAdvisors(Calgary)ULC,andBrianHunter,07Civ.6682(DC)(S.D.N.Y.,May21,2007). 18BrianHunter,130FERC¶ 63,004(2010),approvedbytheCommissioninBrianHunter,135 FERC¶ 61,054(2011).NotethattheCFTCandFERCsettledtheirdisputeswithallotherparties inAugust,2009.SeeConsentOrderofPermanentInjunction,CivilMonetaryPenaltyandOtherReliefas to Defendants Amaranth Advisors, L.L.C. and Amaranth Advisors (Calgary) ULC, United States CommodityFuturesTradingCommissionv.AmaranthAdvisors,L.L.C.,etal.,07Civ.6682(DC)(S.D.N.Y., August12,2009),andOrderApprovingUncontestedSettlement,128FERC¶ 61,154(August12,2009).

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 263 butservedonlytoincreasethevalueofAmaranth’stargetedfinancialpositions. Hunter’schoicetobuyfuturesbefore,yetliquidateinto,thesettlementperiod in which the price of the derivatives was formed thus exploited the nexus betweenthemanipulation’striggersandtargets. 2.2.2. Energy Transfer Partners, L.P. (ETP) In 2007, the FERC accused ETP of manipulating natural gas prices at the HoustonShipChannel(HSC)tradinghubfromDecember2003toDecember 2005.19ETPwasaccusedofintentionallylosingmoneyonitsindexsettingsales of monthly fixedprice natural gas at HSC to benefit its physical and financial positions that were short to the published index price at that location. The allegation thus asserted that ETP triggered the manipulation by intentionally making uneconomic pricemaking sales to lower the value of the HSC index, which served as the nexus to benefit the value of ETP’s targeted pricetaking positions.Thecasesettledfor$30millioninpenaltiesanddisgorgement.20 2.2.3. DiPlacido In 2001, the CFTC accused trader Anthony J. DiPlacido and others with the manipulationoftwoWesternelectricitytradinghubsin1998.21Themanipulation involved the placement of uneconomic purchases or sales during the settlementoftheNYMEXelectricityfuturescontractsacrossseveralmonths, causingdirectionalpricemovementsthatbenefitedpricetakingcontractsheld byAvista,theiremployerandclient.Avistaanditsemployeessettled,leaving DiPlacido (who was a NYMEX floor broker) as the lone defendant. The CFTCapprovedadeterminationbyanadministrativelawjudgeofDiPlacido’s liabilityonfourofthefivecountsin2008.22ThiswasaffirmedinU.S.District Court in 2009, which noted that DiPlacido “intentionally paid more than he would have had to pay for the purpose of causing the closing quotation to increase.”23 This successful application of the CEA’s artificial price standard

19EnergyTransferPartners,L.P.,etal.,OrdertoShowCauseandNoticeofPenalties(2007). 20 Order Approving Uncontested Settlement in Docket No. IN063003, 128 FERC ¶61,269 (August 31, 2009). The CFTC also brought an action against ETP with substantially similar allegationsthatsettledfor$10million.SeeReleasePR547108,EnergyTransferPartners,L.P.and ThreeofItsSubsidiariestoPaya$10MillionPenaltytoSettleCFTCActionAllegingAttempted Manipulation of Natural Gas Prices (March 17, 2008), available at http://www.cftc.gov/ PressRoom/PressReleases/pr547108.html. 21SeeIntheMatterof:AnthonyJ.DiPlacido,RobertS.Kristufek,andWilliamH.Taylor,available athttp://www.cftc.gov/files/enf/01orders/enfavistacomplaint.pdf(August21,2001). 22InreDiPlacido,Comm.Fut.L.Rep.(CCH)P30,970(November5,2008). 23DiPlacidov.CFTC,2009U.S.App.LEXIS22692(2dCir.Oct.16,2009).Morerecently,the FERC settled a $245 million claim against Constellation Energy Commodities Group for

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 264 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 demonstrates that the framework explains the cause and effect of the manipulation,whilethecalculationofanartificialpricemeasuresthateffect. 2.2.4. Sumitomo Corporation (Sumitomo) From1995through1996,theCFTCallegedthatSumitomomanipulatedthe worldmarketforcopperbycorneringtheentirewarehousesupplyavailableto the London Metals Exchange.24 By concentrating purchases in one location, SumitomotraderYasuoHamanakawasabletosignificantlyraisepricesonthe exchange, pressuring global spot and futures prices for copper to create backwardationintheforwardpricingcurve.Subsequently,Hamanakawasable to liquidate Sumitomo’s holdings at a premium in global metals markets, including the Comex Division of the NYMEX. After regulator interest promptedcessationofthecorner,worldcopperpricesfellsignificantly,causing Sumitomotolosebillionsofdollars(Holley,1996).Hamanakawasdeterminedto haveaccomplishedthecornerthroughcontroloflessthanfivepercentofthe physicalcoppersupply. By concentrating Sumitomo’s small globalmarket share at one location to benefit the value of its broader portfolio, Hamanaka was able to focus his pricemakingtransactionstotriggeradirectionalpricemovementthatwould increase the value of Sumitomo’s pricetaking positions. This was not an exerciseofmarketpower,butratheralessonastohowtheframeworkapplies to a market corner. The pricemaking trades initiate the corner by causing a (real or perceived) shortage to emerge.25 The shortage causes the price to increaseandpromptsotherstosellshortintothemarkettocapitalizeonwhat isperceivedasaninflatedprice.Ultimately,themanipulator’scontinuedbuying initiatesasqueeze,whereinshortsellersscrambletocovertheirpositionsinan escalating market. Their buying drives the price higher still, allowing the manipulator to sell out of its accumulated position as a pricetaker to the coveringshorts.Themanipulatorprofitsonallsuchtradesuntilthepanicto coversubsides.Subsequently,themarketpricefalls,causingthemanipulatorto losemoneyonwhateverunitsitstillholds.Thus,acornerdiffersfromother lossbasedmanipulationsonlyinthetimingofthelossrelativetothegain.

allegedlymanipulatingvariouscontractsinthreeEasternwholesaleelectricitymarkets. SeeConstellationEnergyCommoditiesGroup,Inc.,138FERC¶ 61,168(2012);andLedgerwoodand Pfeifenberger(2012). 24IntheMatterofSumitomoCorporation,anorderreferencedinCFTCPressRelease#414498 andavailableathttp://www.cftc.gov/ogc/oporders98/ogcfsumitomo.htm(May11,1998). 25Thisexampleisconsistentwiththecharacterizationof acornerpresentedbyDr.Pirrong throughhisvariousworksonpoint.See,forexample,Pirrong(2004).

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 265

TheSumitomocasealsoprovidesanexcellentexampleofhowtheconceptof traditional market power has been consistently misapplied in the context of market manipulation triggered by uneconomic behavior. Hamanaka’s ability to sustain a corner with a five percent market share was enabled through his willingness to uneconomically trigger a shortage at the pricemaking delivery pointthatwaskeytoinfluencingtheworldcopperprice(thenexus)tobenefit his broader, targeted pricetaking spot sales. This provides insight into the axiomaticparadoxofwhymarketpowerdoesnotnecessarilyequatewithmarket share.Traditionalmarketpowerwithattendanthighmarketshareisneededto resistcompetitiveforcesandcauseadirectionalpricemovementthatbenefitsits holder on a standalone basis. By comparison, the “market power” needed to moveapriceinadirectionthatisinjurioustoatrader’sselfinterestrequiresonly the “market share” associated with concentrating uneconomic trades of sufficient size to bias the pricemaking mechanism enough to trigger the manipulation.Asweprovelater,thisabilitydependslessonmarketpowerthan on the manipulator’s ability to overwhelm the ephemeral illiquidity associated withtemporalinelasticityofmarketsupplyordemand. 2.2.5. SEC Cases SEC case precedent under Rule 10b5 has involved a spectrum of behavior ruled as manipulative under its fraudbased provisions, albeit without a commoneconomicfoundation.Behaviorsuchas“markingtheclose”involves theuseofuneconomictradesattheendofthetradingdaytobiasanasset’s closingprice,triggeringamanipulationtobenefitthetrader’srelatedpositions. ThiswasprohibitedinSECv.Masri,basedonthepremisethat“butforthe manipulative intent, the defendant would not have conducted the transaction.”26Thisandothertypesofintentionallyheavytradingdesignedto take advantage of ephemeral illiquidity have been ruled illegal because “inaccurate information is being injected into the marketplace” by the price movements triggered thereby.27 Unfortunately, the standards of proof set by thesecasesaresufficientlynebulousastocomplicatefutureenforcementtothe extentthat“itisdifficulttodistinguishpredatorytradingfrommarketdepth

26SECv.Masri,523F.Supp2d361,372372(S.D.N.Y.2007).SeealsoMarkowskiv.SEC,274 F.3d 525, 529 (D.C.Cir.2001) (“‘manipulation’ can be illegal solely because of the actor’s purpose”).TheCFTCalsobringsantimanipulationenforcementactionsforsuchactivity.For example,seeCFTCv.OptiverUS,LLCetal.,Case1:08cv06560LAP(S.D.N.Y.2012)(alleged “bangingtheclose”ofNYMEXoilfutures). 27GFLAdvantageFund,Ltd.v.Colkitt,272F.3d189, 205(2001)(allegedmanipulationby a holder of a short position who was asserted to have sold shares aggressively to induce other holders of the stock to sell). The term “predatory trading” was used in this context by BrunnermeierandPedersen(2005).

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 266 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 orordinary”(KyleandViswanathan,2008:243).Theuseofthe framework, and in particular the recognition of the concept of uneconomic tradingasamanipulationtrigger,couldhelpprovidesomestructuretothese andsimilaranalyses. Theframeworkalsoappliestocasesofoutrightfraudwherethemanipulator introduces false information into the market but does not necessarily participatedirectlyinthetriggeringtrades.Forexample,tradersin“pumpand dump” schemes buy stock positions in advance of disseminating false informationtoinduceotherstobuythestock,whichthentriggerstheupward pricemovementthatbenefitsthemanipulator’s(pricetaking)salesofthestock afterthepriceincrease.28Indeed,theonlydifferencebetweenthisscenarioand oneofuneconomictradingisthepartyinjuredbythetrigger.Inbothcases,the trades that trigger the manipulation are uneconomic and incur losses. The differenceisthat,inthecaseofoutrightfraud,thelossesareincurredbythe fraud’svictims,notbythemanipulator. OthertypesoffraudulentbehaviorprohibitedundertheSEC’srulesdonot necessarilyresultinapricemovementandthusarenotdirectlydescribedby thepricebasedmanipulationframeworkwepresentinthispaper.Forexample, “wash trades” executed to create churn to boost perceptions of volumetric trade(eitherofthetraderortheassettraded)donotnecessarilycreateaprice effectnorgeneratelosses(savetransactionscosts).29Similarly,tradingbasedon insideinformationisamisappropriationofinformationinbreachofafiduciary duty,30possiblyfallingunderthedefinitionofamarketmanipulationbutnot necessarily with a verifiable price effect. This does not mean the general structureoftheframeworkcouldnotadapttoexplainsuchcases.Forexample, washtradestriggeranincreaseintradingvolume,whichmayactasthenexus toconveyfalseinformationastothesizeofthetrader’sbook(thetarget).A government official may use inside information about pending congressional legislation(thetrigger)toinvestinacompany’sstock(thetarget)priortothe announcementofapendingbillthatwillpositivelyaffectthestock’sprice(the

28 Intentional dissemination of false information is specifically prohibited by Sections 9a2 through 9a4 of the Exchange Act. See also the complaint filed in SEC v. Pawel Dynkowski etal.,CaseNo.09361(May20,2009),whichisavailableonlineathttp://www.sec.gov/litigation/ complaints/2009/comp21053.pdf.Note thatuneconomic transactions can also accompany pump anddumpschemesifthemanipulatorpurchasesstocktohelpfuelthebuyingfrenzy. 29WashtradesarespecificallyprohibitedunderSection9a1oftheSecuritiesAct. 30The“misappropriationtheory”isderivedfromU.S.v.O'Hagan,521U.S.642,652(1997). InsidertradingisprohibitedunderSection10b51oftheSecuritiesAct.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 267 nexus).31 Though we do not discuss it further, the general logic of the framework could thus tie together the analyses of various applications by exploringthedifferentlinkagesthatcanserveasstablenexuses. 2.2.6. KeySpan-Ravenswood, LLC (KeySpan) InFebruary,2008,theFERCissuedareportseekingtocloseaninvestigation of KeySpan for allegedly manipulating the New York wholesale electricity capacitymarket.32Amongotherthings,theFERCStafffoundthata“swap” arrangement between KeySpan and another market participant that incented the raising of bids into the market was not collusive, not fraudulent, and pursuedalegitimatebusinesspurpose.Thus,whiletheswap(thetarget)would benefitfromhigherbidsbyKeySpan(thetrigger)toraisecapacityprices(the nexus),theFERCruledthatKeySpan’sbehaviordidnottriggeramanipulation because it was neither outright fraudulent nor uneconomic, nor did it constituteanexerciseofmarketpowerbecauseitwasallowedunderthethen existing FERCapproved tariff. Lacking any of the three characteristics that could spark a pricebased manipulation, the FERC determined that the behavior complained of was legitimate and thus could not be manipulative. However, this did not deter the U.S. Department of Justice (DOJ) from pursuingitsownanalysisofthebehaviorbasedonacomplaintfiledregarding manipulating the market in violation of the Sherman Act §1, 15 U.S.C. §1 (1890),whichprohibitsconspiraciesinrestraintoftrade. TheDOJ’sinvestigationofKeySpanultimatelyconcludedwithaconsent decreewhereinthecompanyagreedtopayadisgorgementof$12million.33 This is a novel outcome, as the DOJ asserted jurisdiction in a manipulation casewherethebehaviorinquestionwaspreviouslydeterminedtobelegitimate by the regulatory agency with primary jurisdiction over the matter. While at first this may seem like an overreach, the result makes sense given the reasoningappliedbytheFERCandthefindingthatanticompetitivebehavior triggered the manipulation. More broadly, because market power benefits its holderonastandalonebasis,transactionsthatreflecttheexerciseofmarket powerservea“legitimatebusinesspurpose”andthuscannotbemanipulative. Iftrueacrosscases,suchlogicwouldsupportDr.Pirrong’sconclusion(stated at the outset of this paper) that agencies with fraudbased antimanipulation

31 This behavior was prohibited by the Stop Trading on Congressional Knowledge Act (the “STOCKAct”),P.L.No:12t105(April4,2012). 32 FERC Enforcement Staff Report: Findings of a NonPublic Investigation of Potential Market Manipulation by Suppliers in the New York City Capacity Market, Docket Nos. IN082000 & EL0739000(February28,2008). 33U.S.v.KeySpanCorp.,Case1:10cv01415WHP,S.D.N.Y.,2011.

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 268 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 statutes cannot properly deter manipulations triggered by the exercise of marketpower,potentiallynecessitatinginterventionbytheDOJinsuchcases. This result derives less from the legal insufficiency of fraudbased statutes thanfromtheinappropriateinterpretationofthelegitimatebusinesspurpose standard.Notwithstandingthelegalityofthetradesthatreflecttheexerciseof marketpower,itisthemanipulator’swillingnesstousesuchtradestotrigger the manipulation that gives rise to the fraudulent device, scheme, or artifice that is actionable under a statute modeled on Rule 10b5. The legitimacy of such trades must be viewed outside the context of the antitrust laws, as behavior that does not necessarily give rise to antitrust liability may nevertheless be intended to cause a directional price movement designed to executeamanipulation.Therefore,separateanalysisoftheframework’strigger mustnotlosesightofthebroadercontextinwhichsuchtradesmayhavebeen placedtoenhancethetrader’spricetakingpositions.

2.3. SUMMARY: THE FRAMEWORK AND EXISTING CASE LAW Table 2 summarizes the examples of pricebased market manipulation discussedinthissectionandidentifiesthetrigger,nexus,andtargetforeach.

Table 2: Summary of Framework Components for Different Examples of Price-Based Manipulations Manipulation Type Trigger Nexus Target Index Manipulations Uneconomic Trading Physical and Derivatives Index Settlement Price (Amaranth, ETP, DiPlacido) (Index) Positions Corners Uneconomic Trading Futures Price Futures (Sumitomo) (Volume) (Near Delivery) Marking the Close Uneconomic Trading Closing Price Credit Requirements, (Masri) (Volume) (Market-to-Market) Derivatives, Stock Fraud Stock Price Stock Position Economic Withholding Market Power Capacity Auction Price Other Physical Capacity (KeySpan)

Thelackofuniformityacrossthesecasesexplainsinpartwhylegalprecedent concerningmarketmanipulationisneitherdeepnorconsistent,exceptwithin narrow categories of behavior. This “I know it when I see it” approach to manipulation analysis perpetuates uncertainty as to future compliance and enforcementrequirements,wastingthescarceresourcesofmarketparticipants andregulatoryagenciesalike.Adoptionof10b5equivalentstatutesreflectsa desire for greater simplicity of enforcement, but this does not necessarily

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 269 equatewithconsistencyofapplication.Focusingonbringingconsistencytothe analysisofmanipulationbyusingaconsistentplatformcouldaddmuchneeded clarityacrosscases,agenciesandstatutes.

2.4. THE FRAMEWORK AND THE EXISTING LITERATURE The subject of market manipulation has received limited treatment in the economic and financial literature in the past two decades. In the early 1990s, authorssuchasFischelandRoss(1991)assertedthatthevagueintentstandardof the (pre–DoddFrank) CEA created inefficiency by overdeterring legitimate tradingbehaviortopreventwhatwasviewedbymanyatthetimeasavictimless crime.Pirrong(1993)brokewiththisconvention,positingthatmanipulationssuch as market corners are statistically measurable phenomena enabled through the exercise of market power and revealed in patterns of behavior that are distinguishable from competitive benchmarks. His later articles and testimony continuedtoadvocatefortheuseofregressionanalysesandotherstatisticaltests to prove or disprove intent and to measure the price effect of manipulative behavior(Pirrong,2004).However,theseworkscontinuedtoexplaintheabilityto execute a manipulation as a function of market power, not uneconomic behavior. This perception led to his ultimate conclusion that fraudbased manipulationstatutesdonotapplytomarketbasedmanipulations(Pirrong,2010). The desire to distinguish “marketbased” manipulation from “fraudbased” manipulation is understandable given historic differences in the statutory treatmentofcasesunderthe10b5andartificialpricestandards.Becausethe firstsuccessfulCFTCenforcementactiondidnotoccuruntil2009,muchof the literature on point focuses on manipulations occurring under 10b5. For example,GerardandNanda(1993)discussedthemanipulationofseasonedequity offerings using secondary markets; Jarrow (1994) studied the manipulation opportunities created by the emerging availability of financial derivatives; Aggarwal and Wu (2003) empirically tested SEC data to discern qualitative elements of stock price manipulations; Attari, Mello and Ruckes (2005) observed that strategic trading can profit from liquidations by large arbitrageurstomanipulatemarkets;GoldsteinandGuembel(2008)concluded that strategic trading causes financial market prices to misrepresent equity values, thereby creating incentives to sell and enabling manipulations; and Massa and Rehman (2008) determined that mutual funds exploit inside informationtoaffiliateabank’spendingloanstolargecustomerstobuild portfoliosofthosecustomer’ssecuritiestimedtotheclosingofthoseloans. Itisnoteworthythattheanalyticalfocusofmuchofthisliteraturecenters uponrelativelynarrowandoftenunrelatedtypesofmanipulativebehavior. By comparison, a relatively deep set of literature exists concerning the

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 270 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 practiceofpricesupport,whichcanbealegalformofmarketmanipulation under certain circumstances. Specifically, Ruud (1993), Prabhala and Puri (1998), and Lewellen (2006) studied the phenomenon of underwriter price supportofstockIPOs,whichisalegalformofpricedbasedmanipulation underSECrules.34GolezandMarin(2012)usedasimilarapproachtoexamine theillegalpracticebymutualfundsofsupportingaparentbank’sstockto limitdownsidemovementsinstressedtimes.Thesestudiesfoundempirical evidence of the presence and effectiveness of price support on financial performanceusingavarietyofstatisticalscreens,theefficacyofwhichwe discuss in Section 4inrelationtothe analysis offramework triggers. The authorsalsotestedtheeffectsofmanipulativebehavioronlessquantifiable aspectsofbusiness,includingreputationeffectsandbenefitstounaffiliated entities,factorsthatwelaterconsiderinrelationtotheanalysisofpossible manipulationtargets. The general lack of analytic portability across case studies prevents the accumulation of a knowledge base for consistently evaluating manipulations across different cases under the same statute and across different statutes. Someauthorshavemadeprogressinbridgingthesegaps.Forexample,Kyle and Viswanathan (2008) build on the earlier works of Allen and Gale (1992), Kumar and Seppi (1992), and others to provide a reconciliation of SEC and CFTC “tradebased” manipulation cases, ultimately finding manipulation occursonlyfromdistortionsof“allocationalefficiencythatrelatestomarket informativeness and transactional efficiency that relates to market liquidity.” Thisfindingsupports,andissupportedby,themodelwepresentinSection3. Likewise, Pirrong (2010) raised the issue of comparability between the anti manipulation statute of the CFTC and the fraudbased statutes of the SEC, FERC,andFTC.However,theseworksdonotconsideruneconomictrading, and they remain influenced by the premise that all manipulations are the product of either outright fraud or the exercise of market power, thus providing no consistent guidance for a trieroffact torely upon in generally evaluatingmanipulativebehavior. Theframeworkweproposeprovidesavehicleforreconcilingtheseissues.By includinguneconomicbehaviorasapotentialtrigger,theanalyticalfoundation for analyzing manipulation shifts from the nebulous search for evidence of market power or outright fraud to evaluating whether the manipulator intentionallyactedinamannerdesignedtotriggerabenefitforitsfinancially leveraged pricetaking positions. Traditional measurements relevant to

34Thiswasoriginallyreferredtoas“Rulel0b7”andwascodifiedas15U.S.C.§10(b)and17C.F.R. §240.l0b7(1934).ThiswaslaterrecodifiedasSection104ofRegulationM,17C.F.R.242.104(1996).

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 271 analyzingmarketpowerarerelevanttothisanalysis,formarketpowerremains a possiblestandalone trigger, marketshare can be concentrated to move an index price, and leverage in pricetaking positions can help enable a manipulation. However, the main precursor for the ability to successfully manipulatemarketsisnotthecontrolofalargemarketshare,buttheabilityto capitalize on temporal illiquidity and to exploit the peculiarities of certain pricingmechanismswithinandacrossmarkets.Thenextsectiondiscussesthe microeconomicfoundationfortheseassertions.

3. THE MICROECONOMICS OF THE FRAMEWORK In this section, we provide a simple and intuitive example of the lossbased manipulation of a market for condominiums that is consistent with our proposedframework.Thisexampledemonstratestheattributesrequiredfora successful manipulation and shows that neither market power nor outright fraudarenecessary.Thisexamplealsoprovidesanopportunitytodiscussthe role that alternative information sets play in evaluating the manipulation, a prerequisitefortheabilitytosuccessfullyidentifymanipulativebehavior.Next, we generalize the example to a cleared market and develop the profit maximizing criteria that create the incentives for the manipulator’s behavior. We use these criteria to identify three factors that underlie the incentive to manipulate.Thesearegivencontextthroughcomparisontothemanipulation casesdiscussedinthepriorsectionandgeneralizedtoincludecasestriggered bymarketpoweroroutrightfraud.

3.1. MANIPULATION OF A CONDOMINIUM PRICE INDEX Assume that twobedroom condominiums are currently selling for around $500,000,asmeasuredbyawebsiteindexthattrackscomparablesalesovera rolling30dayperiodandisreliedonbytheindustryasthecompetitiveprice for“comps”inthearea.Manyunitsareforsale,allaboutthesameandoffered atpricesaround$500,000.Ifyouownedasimilarcondoandwantedtosellitat a price above market ($700,000, for instance), you would be unlikely to succeed.Thisisbecauseyourabilitytoraiseyourpricesignificantlyabovethe competitivepriceisconstrainedbytheothersellersinthemarket,ahallmark ofeffectivecompetitionthatcheckssellermarketpower. Comparethistoascenariowhereyouofferyourcondoforapricesignificantly below market ($100,000, for example). Such an offer would be immediately snapped up, the buyer walking away with a windfall while you incur a loss (relativetoyouropportunitycost)ofaround$400,000.Thisdemonstratesapoint essentialtounderstandingalossbasedmanipulation:thefurtheroneiswillingto

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 272 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 droptheirofferbelowthecompetitivemarketprice,thegreaterthelikelihood that they will effectively face no competition from other sellers.35 The same principleholdsforbuyersthatbidatpricesabovethecompetitiveequilibrium, underscoringthepointthatmarketparticipantsdonotneedmarketpowernor needtocommitoutrightfraudtosuccessfullyexecutetrades(andthereforepost prices)inamannerthatinjurestheirstandaloneselfinterest. As discussed previously, uneconomic trades can trigger a market manipulation.Assumetherewerepreviously19salesontheindexsuchthatthe $100,000saleofyourcondolowerstheaverageindexvalueofcondossoldto $480,000.Ifothersellersrelyontheindexpriceforevaluatingthemarketvalue of their condos, they will lower their prices in response. You then buy 50 condosfor$480,000each,witheachpurchasemadeattheindexprice(i.e.,asa price taker). By willingly taking a loss of $400,000 on your initial sale that tankedtheindex,yousaved$1millionacrossthe50condos(at$20,000each) that you ultimately buy, netting a $600,000 gain.36 This is a market manipulationbecauseananomalouspricesettingtransactionwasintentionally usedforthesolepurposeofmovingapricetobenefitapricetakingposition. Thecontrarianmayassertthatthesuccessofthisschemedependsuponthe willingnessofthemanipulatortobuymorecondominiumsthanpresentlyreside ontheindex,thusfacilitatingthemanipulationthroughtheuseofmarketpower. This is incorrect, however, because the 50 condominiums purchased are as a pricetakertotheindexandthusirrelevanttosettingtheprice.Thisunderscores three essential elements of manipulation. First, the success of a manipulation requires the ability to substantially move the price that is to serve as the manipulation’snexus,inthiscasewithanuneconomictrade.Thisrelatestothe temporalliquidityofthemarket,whichisafunctionoftheelasticityofsupply anddemand.Second,themanipulatormustaccumulatesufficientleverageinthe targetedpricetakingpositionssuchthatthebenefitoutweighsthelossonthe trigger (Kleit, 2009). Deep pockets that can afford to accumulate size in the

35Ofcourse,thefurtherawayfromthecompetitivepricesuchatradeisexecuted,thegreater thelikelihoodthatitwillbeignoredbyothermarketparticipantsasanomalousanddetectedby regulatorsassuspicious.ThisisconsistentwithHellwig,whonotedthat“inalargemarket,the equilibrium price will reflect only those elements of information that are common to a large numberofagents.Becauseanindividualagentdoesnotaffecttheprice,hisinformationenters thepriceonlytotheextentthatitissharedbyotheragents”(Hellwig,1980:479). 36Thisplanwillprofitonlyifanumberofconditionsexist,mostimportantly(1)thattheindex continuestobetrustedandusedbyothersellersasameasureofthecompetitiveprice,(2)that theimpactthesalewillhaveontheindexwillbemorethansufficienttorecoupyour$400,000 opportunity cost (i.e., causing a greater than $8,000 average price reduction across the 50 condominiums that you intend to buy), and (3) that scarcity pricing will not cause sellers to demandpremiumstotheindexsuchthattheschemebecomesunprofitable.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 273 targetedportfolioandtoabsorblossesonthetriggeringtradesthereforeimprove thelikelihoodofsuccess,areasonwhypositionlimitsonderivativesmightbean effective (albeit clumsy) antimanipulation tool. Third, smaller losses in the trigger make the manipulation more likely to be profitable. Aside from enforcementconsiderations,thismeansthatmanipulationstriggeredbyoutright fraudormarketpoweraremorelikelytobesuccessful,asoutrightfraudincurs nocostinthetriggerandmarketpowerexercisedasatriggerisprofitabletothe manipulatoronastandalonebasis.

3.2. THE ROLE OF INFORMATION SETS ON ECONOMIC VERSUS UNECONOMIC BEHAVIOR A key criticism of the condominium example and of the analyses of other manipulationcasesinvolvinguneconomictradingisthatthebehaviorassertedto triggeramanipulationcouldalwaysberationalizedaslegitimateinthecontextof a different information set held privately by the manipulator. For example, if facedwithamanipulationclaimforyouractivitiesinthecondominiummarket, youmightprovideevidenceshowinganyofthefollowing:  Your sale of the original condominium at a price far below market was economic given your true willingness to sell, private knowledge of that unit’sdeficiencies,andoutlookonthemarketgenerally,thusnegatingyour intenttotriggeramanipulation.  Themagnitudeoftheimpactyoursalehadontheindexwasdependenton a litany of factors such as calculation mechanics and liquidity that were completelyoutsideyourcontrol,suchthatyoucouldnotpredictthesale’s impactonthenexus.  Your subsequent purchase of the 50 condominiums was a legitimate response to the price decline you observed in the market and, in fact, providedpricesupporttoassurethatregionalcondominiumpricesdidnot fallfurtherthantheydid. Indeed,thispointstoaninherentlyrecursivelogicthatcomplicatestheproofof all pricebased manipulations: the same price movements that define the outcomeofasuccessfulmanipulationmaysimultaneouslysupporttheeconomic rationality of the trades comprising the manipulation’s trigger and target, thus casting the agent executing the scheme not as a manipulator, but as a savvy traderwhowasrewardedforcorrectlyrelyingonitsprivateinformationset. Thesolutiontothisproblemisnotassimpleasestablishingtheexistenceof each of the framework’s components or the timing of when they were assembled–indeed,legitimateriskmanagementandhedgingstrategiesrequire

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 274 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 atradertoestablishtargetedpositionsinadvanceoftriggeringpricemovements tobeeffective.Noristhesolutionsolelyafunctionofprovingastablenexus, astheexistenceofacorrelationbetweenthesizeofthelossinthetriggerand the benefit derived from the target does not mean that the relationship was intentionally exploited. Nor is showing standalone losses in the trigger sufficientproof,forapproximatelyhalfofalltradesexecutedinafairmarket shouldlosemoney.Norisprovinganartificialpricenecessarilydispositive,for thefraudbasedstatutesandpost–DoddFrankCEAdonotrequireproofofa onetoonemappingofcauseandeffectinordertoassertaclaimofattempted manipulation.Theseevidentiaryconcernshaveledsomeauthorstoconclude that“withregardtotradebasedmanipulation,itmaybedifficultorimpractical for the legal system to define and enforce such schemes as illegal price manipulation”(KyleandViswanathan,2008:278). Such skepticism presumes that the revealed manifestations of the manipulator’s actions are not distinguishable from other types of “noise” presentinthemarketplacedata,aconclusionthatfollowsonlyiftheefficient marketshypothesisholdssuchthat“atanytimepricesfullyreflectallavailable information” (Fama, 1970:383). Specifically, in a large market, the equilibrium pricereflectsonlythoseelementsofinformationthatarecommonlyknownto alargenumberofagents.Becauseanindividual(pricetaking)agentdoesnot affect the price, such information enters the equilibrium price only to the extent that it is shared by other agents. Attempts at pricebased market manipulation are thus irrelevant in this environment as they contribute only noisetothemarketdatathatisultimatelyeitherfilteredoutoroverwhelmedby theweaklawoflargenumbers(Hellwig,1980:479,493). This perspective presumes that sufficient liquidity is present in the market such that the wouldbe manipulator is rendered a price taker and that all intentionally injected misinformation (whether in the form of uneconomic trading or outright fraud) would be muted by, or discarded in favor of, the clarity of a true equilibrium. However, this would also mean that informed traders in otherwise competitive markets could never earn a return on their information. If information is very inexpensive (the trigger is cheap) or if informed traders have very precise information (thus providing ephemeral market power), then the resulting equilibrium price will reveal most of the informed traders’ information because “such markets are likely to be thin” (Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980). If detected by other market participants through efficientmarkets,anysuccessfulmanipulationundersuchcircumstanceswould induceselfcorrectingliquidityduetoarbitrage(HansonandOprea,2009).Thisisa misnomer,however,astheprivatenatureoftheinformationthatallowedthe manipulationtooccurcouldalsoobscureitsdetection.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 275

Theframeworkweproposeoffersapotentialmethodfordisentanglingthis informational conundrum by focusing on differentiating the anomalous outcomesofmanipulativebehaviorfromthenoiseotherwisepresentedbythe normalfunctioningofamarketplace.Thispotentialderivesfromtwosources. First, separating the manipulation’s pricemaking and pricetaking trades provides a logical foundation for separating cause and effect. Second, identifying the specific types of behavior that could trigger a manipulation simplifiesthecreationofscreensfordetectinganomalouspricemakingtrades. While we defer the discussion of screens that could be used to detect such behavioruntilSection4,wenotethatapresumptionoflegitimacywillattachto all open market trades as a null hypothesis. The burden falls on the party allegingthemanipulationtoprovethatthebehaviorinquestionrejectedthis hypothesis and thus fell outside of the level of market noise associated with legitimacy. The ability of a market participant to strategically use private information to manipulate a market is then demonstrated by showing its temporal ability to exert a price effect, which ultimately depends on market liquidity. The condominium example provides a specific case of this phenomenonbyconsideringanindexasthepricemakingmechanismforthe market.Inthenextsection,wegeneralizethisresultbyextendingthemodelof lossbasedopportunismtothecontextofaclearedmarket.

3.3. THE MICROECONOMICS OF THE DECISION TO MANIPULATE Togeneralizethecondominiumexampletoabroadercontext,itishelpfulto changethemarketpricingmechanismfromanindextoaclearedcompetitive model,showninFigure1. Figure 1: Net Social Welfare Loss from Below-Market Sales

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 276 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

Absentmanipulation,thismarketclearsatthecompetitiveequilibrium“α ”at thepricePx*andquantitytradedX*.Themanipulatorinthisexampleoffersa quantity(XmXr )ofthegoodintothemarketasapricetaker.Theresulting market equilibrium “χ” lies below and to the right of the competitive equilibrium and beneath the market supply curve, resulting in the lower “artificial” price Pm and higher quantity traded Xm, with the manipulator supplyingthequantity(Xm–Xr )tothemarketandcompetitorslefttosellthe remainingunitsXr.Buyersarethrilledbythisactivity,astheconsumersurplus increasesbyanamountequaltotheareaPx*,α,χ,Pm.However,allofthis gainisoffsetbyalossofprofitsofthemanipulator(areaβ,χ,δ )andofthe otherwouldbecompetitivesellers(areaPx*,α,δ,Pm).Thisresultsinanet societallossofwelfareshownbythetriangleα,β,χ. Figure 1 demonstrates why traditional microeconomic tools used to detect market power are illequipped to analyze lossbased manipulation. Whereas participantspossessingmarketpowerareincentedtowithholdoutputfromthe market, this manipulator is incented to cause the market to overproduce. The profitabilitycriterionfortheaboveexampleisgivenby (1) ( * − ) ⋅ > − ⋅ ()( − PmCmXrXmRPmPx ). Totheleftoftheinequality,therevenuefromthemanipulationincreasesas thefinancialleverageoftherelatedshortposition“R”heldbythemanipulator increases or as the price decrease below the competitive price caused bythe manipulation(Px*–Pm)increases.Totherightoftheinequality,thecostof themanipulationgrowsasthesizeofthetriggeringoffer(Xm–Xr)growsor astheperunitlosstothemanipulator(Cm–Pm≥0)worsens. Figure 2: Generalization of the Loss-Based Framework

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 277

AsshowninFigure2,theprofitabilitycriterioncanbegeneralizedtoaccount forlossbasedmanipulationstriggeredbyexcessivesalesbysubstituting“G ” fortheperunitgainmadebythemanipulator,“L”fortheperunitlossinthe trigger,and“X ”forthesizeofthetrigger.Theresultingprofitabilitycriterion isgivenbyEquation2.

(2) G ⋅ R > L ⋅ X . Assumefirstthatthemanipulatorwantstomaximizetheprofitability(π)ofa targeted derivatives position of fixed size R by varying the size of its price makingtriggeringtransactionXshowninFigure2.Becausesupplyanddemand are linear in this example, R is horizontal while the functions of G and L are linearandupwardsloping.TheresultingTotalRevenuecurveislinear,whereas theTotalCostcurveisincreasingandconcaveup.TheseareshowninFigure3.

Figure 3: Profit Maximization of a Market Manipulation

Profitmaximizationoccurswherethemarginalrevenuefromthemanipulation trigger is equal to its marginal cost, shown by the quantity X ^ in Figure 3. However,themanipulationisprofitableforanysizedtriggerlessthanXMax , suggesting that a trader could have significant room for error should it contemplatetriggeringamanipulativescheme.TheprofitcriterioninEquation2 canbemaximizedgenerallyinthiscircumstanceas

∂G ∂L ∂R (3a) maxπ XLRG ⇒⋅−⋅= R −⋅ LX =−⋅ 00 ⇒= ∂X ∂ X ∂X

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 278 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

∂G ∂ X (3b) X ^ = R −⋅ ⋅ L . ∂L ∂L Therefore,theprofitmaximizingtriggerX^isafunctionoftheperunitlossin the trigger, the slopes of the market supply and demand curves, and the leveragebuiltintherelatedpositions. 3.3.1. The Cost of the Manipulation Trigger (L) Theperunitlossonthebidorofferusedtotriggerthemanipulationshouldbe measured relative to the opportunity cost the manipulator incurs for those units. As discussed previously, this presents a challenge to evaluating manipulativebehavior,foratradercanvalidlyassertthatitsabilitytoobserve whatisforensicallyshowntobeasuperioropportunitywasunclearatthetime a trade was executed. A savvy manipulator can use this to its advantage by placingtriggersatpricesthatareprofitableonanaccountingbasisbutthatfail tocoveritsopportunitycost.Thepartyseekingtoprovethemanipulationmay thenfaceadifficultburdenofprovingthatabetterpricewasavailableandthat themanipulatorintentionallyanduneconomicallyundercutthatprice. 3.3.2. The Slopes of Market Supply and Demand (Liquidity) AsFigure2suggests,asX^increasesinsize,thesizeoftheaveragelossLwill increase and will exceed the increase in the average gain G if the curve associatedwiththemanipulation(supplyforuneconomicoffers,demandfor uneconomicbids)hasanonzeroslope.Becausethesizeoftheaverageloss willthenincreaseasX^increases,itmustthenholdthat ∂G ∂ X (4a) and (4b) 0 < < 1 , 0 < ∈ (),0^ XX . ∂L ∂L Max

These properties inform the development of an elasticity to measure the sensitivityoflossestochangesinthesizeofthemanipulationtrigger.Dividing Equation(3b)byXyields

∂G R ∂ X L ∂G R (5a) 1 = −⋅ =⋅ E ⇒−⋅ ∂L X ∂L X ∂L X ,XL

∂G R ∂ X (5b) E = >−⋅ XL > 0,,01 . , XL ∂L X ∂L

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 279

Astheslopeofthesupplyordemandcurvesbecomesteeper,agreaterlossis incurred for a given trigger X, thus causing EL,X to increase. Equation (5b) demonstrates that this can enhance the environment for manipulation by making a smaller volumetric trigger sufficient to execute the manipulation (making the trigger cheaper), by increasing the ratio of marginal gains to marginal losses (strengthening the nexus), or by making manipulations more profitable for any given size of the derivatives position targeted by the manipulation(strengtheningthetarget). This underscores the role that liquidity plays in the success or failure of manipulations. Inelastic demand or supply is symptomatic of illiquid bids or offers,respectively,thusmakingamanipulationmorelikelytobeprofitableif pricemovementsaredirectionallyaimedatthethinsideofthemarket.Ifan agent’sprivateinformationsetgivesittheabilitytopredicttimeswhensuch thinnessislikelytooccur,itcancoordinateitspricemakingeffortsaccordingly totriggeramanipulation.37Ifmarketsareefficient,othermarketparticipants willperceivetheopportunityandarbitrageawayfutureefforts.Conversely,if the pattern of thinness is irregular or, more likely, if the manipulator can influencewhenandwhethersuchilliquidityemerges(bytheexerciseofmarket power, the execution of uneconomic trades, or the commission of outright fraud),theabilitytosuccessfullyrepeatthemanipulationovertimeincreases. This possibility may support the logic of investigating and bringing enforcement actions against attempted manipulations, for the failure of such attempts mightonly reflect that the wouldbe manipulator misjudged or was testingthedepthofmarketliquidityitfacedatparticularmomentsintime. Severaloftheenforcementactionsdiscussedpreviouslyvalidatethelinkage of demand andsupply elasticity and manipulation.InAmaranth, traderBrian Hunter’s “experiment” sought to exploit and exacerbate temporal inelasticity of theNYMEXbidstack to execute trades at lowprices that would benefit Amaranth’stargetedshortderivativespositions.ETPwasalsoallegedtohave created and exploited temporal inelasticity of bids in executing fixedprice tradesdesignedtolowerthevalueofanindex.InDiPlacido,anenergybroker was successfully prosecuted for “offering through”bids, taking advantage of inelasticitytoposthighpricesduringtheNYMEXsettlementperiodtoraise the profitability of its related options position. Sumitomo trader Yasuo HamanakacreatedinelasticitythroughhiscorneringofcopperontheLondon Metals Exchange. In Masri, an equity trader allegedly “marked the close” by

37AsobservedbyGolezandMarin(2012:31)withrespecttopricesupportprovidedbymutual fundsinbuyingthesecuritiesoftheirparentintimesofeconomicstress,“inturmoiltimesasmall buyinitiatedtrademayhavethesamepriceimpactthanaverylargepurchaseinnormaltimesas investorsmayviewtheformerorderasnew(positive)informationarrivingtothemarket.”

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 280 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 placingalargenumberofbidsattheendofthetradingday,playinguponthe inabilityoftheofferstacktoreplenishitselfintimetoreacttothehigherprice and reflecting temporal inelasticity of supply. That three of these five cases involvedtheenergysectorisnotincidental,forenergymarketsrelyheavilyon publishedindicesforpriceformationbasedonsamplesurveysofarelatively smallnumberofphysicaltransactionsandareprone,thereby,tofrequentor episodicissuesofpriceinelasticityofdemandandsupply.38 3.3.3. The Leverage of Related Positions Theimportanceofleverageinthesizeofthepricetakingpositionrelativeto the size of the trigger is mathematically verifiable from the right side of Equation(5b):

∂G R ∂G R ∂L (6) 01 ⇒>−⋅ 1 R >⇒>⋅ ⋅ X. ∂L X ∂L X ∂G

∂G ∂L Thus,sincebyEquation(4a)0 < < 1,then > 1andtherefore ∂L ∂G (7) > XR .

The manipulator gains leverage by acquiring positions that reference the market price, including financial derivatives and physical contracts traded at settlement.Thisexampleraisestwoimportantpoints.First,becausethetrader must have leverage in its pricetaking positions to successfully execute the manipulation,pricetakingpositionsthatareintotallessthanorequaltothe sizeofthetriggermustbeconsideredahedgetopricerisk,notatargetfor manipulation. This explains the logic of enduser exemptions and position limitsincommoditiesmarkets,39butmakesaratherstrongassumptionthatall pricetakingpositionsareobservable.Second,Equation(7)requiresfinancial, notphysical,leverage.40Somepricetakingpositionsmaynotmatchonetoone with the triggering trades. For example, outofthemoney options held in quantitiesthataremultiplesoftheunderlyingassettradedmayserveonlyasa hedge at some prices, butmay gain leverage as strikeprices are approached.

38Forathoroughdiscussionoftheevolutionofantimanipulationstatutesrelevanttowholesale electricityandnaturalgasmarketsintheU.S.andEurope,seeLedgerwoodandHarris(2012). 39SeePositionLimitsforFuturesandSwaps;FinalRuleandInterimFinalRule,17C.F.R.Parts1, 150 and 151 (2011); http://www.cftc.gov/LawRegulation/DoddFrankAct/Rulemakings/ DF_11_EndUser/index.htm(enduserexemptions). 40SpecialthankstoMatthewL.Hunterforthemanyconversationsthatclarifiedthispoint.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 281

Otherpositionsthatareimprovedbyamanipulationmaynotbequantifiable, such as qualitative benefits to reputation or to parties other than the manipulator(GolezandMarin,2012:7).ForapplicationofthelogicofEquation(7), onemustthereforebemindfulthatitisthetotalnetfinancialleverageheldby the suspected manipulator that incents the manipulation and, therefore, that requiresevaluationrelativetothetarget. Theonlylimitsonthesizeoffinancialpositionsthemanipulatorcanaccrue are its funds available for the scheme, the willingness of counterparties to executecontractsthatbenefititstargetedposition,andregulatorycontrolssuch as exchangebased position limits. Indeed, it is the relative ease of acquiring such positions that drivesmany of thereportingrequirements envisionedby DoddFrank.Bycomparison,deliveryconstraintslimittheassemblageofprice takingphysicalpositionsandmaylimitthenumberofavailablecounterparties thatareabletotrade.Notethattheaccumulationofaphysicalindexposition providesamanipulatorwithavaluableoption;itcankeepthepositionaspart ofitsportfolioofrelatedpositions(R),ortradeunitsoutofthatpositionata fixed price, thus using a pricetaking position to generate pricemaking trades. Holdingphysicalindexbasedpositionsinadditiontoacomplementaryfinancial position enhances the potential for a successful manipulation, because uneconomic fixedprice trades can then be used to simultaneously flatten physicalobligationsandbenefitanyremainingfinancialandphysicalpositions.41 A trader may cite the risk associated with such leveraged positions and characterizethemaslegitimatespeculativeinvestments,capableofgenerating losses or gains. It is true that these positions place the manipulator (and its counterparties) at risk of unfavorable price movements, as evidenced by the demise of Amaranth. However, this risk is not borne equally, because the ability and willingness of the manipulator to influence the market price to benefit its leveraged pricetaking positions biases the likely outcome in a mannerthatcounterpartiescouldnotpredict.Forthisreason,intentionalloss based trading should be viewed as a type of transactional fraud. If the manipulatorintroducesaclearedpricesettingtransactiontothemarketthatis below its true willingness to sell or above its true willingness to pay, the resulting trade potentiates a loss to the manipulator’s counterparties in the targeted markets that they could not reasonably foresee when trading in an

41ThisisthemechanismallegedlyusedintheETPmanipulation.Asthemanipulator’sshareof thetotalvolumeoffixedpricetradesapproaches100%,theaveragepriceofthesetradesequals thepriceusedtovalueitsphysicalindexposition,suchthattheperunitcostofthemanipulation effectively approaches zero (plus or minus any discounts or premiums relating to those transactions).Thiscompoundsthedifficultyofprovingthemanipulation,becauseanactualor opportunitycostseparatefromthemanipulatedindexmaynotexist.

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 282 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 ostensiblycompetitivemarket.Theresultingtransferofwealtharises,notdue tosuperiorforesightorbusinessacumen,butbecausethepricemakingagent ononesideofthepositioniswillingtoexecuteanartificetothedetrimentof the other. The harm caused by such behavior is potentially significant and lasting,asisdiscussedinthenextsection.

4. IDENTIFYING, DETECTING AND MEASURING THE HARM CAUSED BY MARKET MANIPULATION When first presented with our proposed framework,some of our colleagues scoffed at the notion that a market manipulation can create inefficiency (or even be possible) within otherwise competitive markets. Counterarguments reflexively surfaced that the directional price movements caused by triggering pricemaking trades will be reversed by opposing competitive forces, and that wealth transfers produced by manipulations present nothing more than transitory, zerosum outcomes. However, such arguments ultimately rely on a presumptionoftransactionallegitimacythatisabsentinthepresenceofoutright fraud,uneconomictrading,ormarketpower.Becausethemanipulatorseeksto intentionally bias the pricemaking mechanism, such trades misrepresent the valueoftheunderlyingassetandunderminethepriceformationprocesstothe extentthatthemarketreliesonthemisinformation.Inthissection,wedescribe theinefficienciesandharmcausedbysuchdistortionsanddiscussmethodsfor theirdetectionandmeasurement.

4.1. THE INEFFICIENCY CAUSED BY MANIPULATION Market manipulation that cannot be effectively arbitraged introduces transactionalandallocativeinefficienciestothemarket(KyleandViswanathan,2008). Transactionalinefficiencyderivesfromtheerosionofconfidenceinthemarket priceasanindicatoroftruevalue.Searchcostsincreaseasmarketagentsare forced to validate prices.If they perceive that a manipulation is directionally biasingprices,agentsinjuredbythismovementmayavoidsomeoralltrading, thus decreasing the liquidity in the pricemaking market. The exit of these tradersreducestheelasticityofsupplyanddemand,therebymakingthemarket thatmucheasiertomanipulate.Thatpricesaremorelikelytobemanipulated preciselyatthetimeswhendemandandsupplyaremostinelasticexacerbates thisbehavior,forthevalueofthepricingmechanismasanaccuratemeasure forevaluatingscarcityisthenfrustrated.Thiswillincreaseandcause wider bidask spreads. The cost of legitimate trading, including hedging, will ultimatelyincreaseasaresult.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 283

Pricebasedmanipulationscreateallocativeinefficiencybycausingthemarket toproduceatapriceandoutputcombinationthat“doesnotreflectlegitimate forces of supply and demand” and which thus reflects the creation of an “artificial price” (CFTC Manipulation Rule, p. 41407). If market power triggers the manipulation,thisallocativeinefficiencyderivesfromthestandard“deadweight loss” of monopoly or monopsony caused by the underexchange of the asset traded if compared to the competitive equilibrium.Conversely, if uneconomic trading is used to trigger the manipulation, the allocative inefficiency derives from theoverexchange of the asset traded relative to a competitive equilibrium, shownbytheNetWelfareLossinFigure1.Theuseofoutrightfraudasatrigger could mimic either of these two outcomes, depending on the relative responsivenessofbuyersandsellerstothefraudulentprice. The oftstated solution to abate efficiency concerns from pricebased manipulationistomaximizetheliquidityinthepriceformationprocessatall times such that manipulative behavior is muted or negated through robust trading. We agree but for the caveat that more volume does not necessarily equatewithgreaterliquidity.Largetraderscapableofservingasmarketmakers to financial derivatives contracts can bring significant liquidity to the market for legitimate hedging and speculation, but can also accumulate financial leverage sufficient to incent the manipulation of prices. Position limits are a less than stellar tool to abate such behavior, as they will arbitrarily preclude some legitimate trading from the market. A better way to enhance market liquidity is to recognize the characteristics that separate legitimate and manipulative trading. The framework we propose identifies three such characteristics:theuseofoutrightfraud,theexerciseofmarketpower,andthe executionofuneconomictrades.Legitimatetradinglacksthesecharacteristics, exemplified by trading to hedge positional risk, to legitimately undercut or outbidcompetitors,ortoexecuteastrategydesignedtomakemoney(relative tothetrader’sopportunitycost)onastandalonebasis.Suchtradesenhance liquidityandimprovemarketefficiencyovertime.

4.2. THE HARM CAUSED BY MANIPULATION The framework provides an analytical basis to assess the harm caused by manipulative behavior when it is found to exist. In this context, the term “harm” is measured by the redistribution of wealth caused either directly or proximately by the directional price movement created by the manipulation. Harmaccruestothreegroups.First,tradersinthepricemakingmarketwho mustdetrimentallyadjusttheirbidsorofferstoaccommodatethemanipulated price are harmed. This would include, for example, sellers priced out of the market due to uneconomic offers, buyers injured by monopoly prices, or

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 284 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 parties induced to trade against their selfinterest on the basis of fraudulent information. Second, the counterparties to the manipulator’s pricetaking instruments are harmed, as are other market participants with equivalent positionalrisk.Third,totheextentthataprovablenexuscanbedemonstrated to future periods or other markets, other parties may demonstrate that they incurredharmaswell. This last point may raise legitimate concerns of potentially limitless liability for behavior determined to be manipulative, requiring a high threshold for proofofthenexus.However,thishighstandarddoesnotnegatethefactthat theeffectsofamanipulationmaylingerbeyonditsexecution.Forexample,in thecaseofthecondominiummanipulationpresentedinSection3,thesizeof theuneconomicpurchasethatwouldbeneededtoreversethe$20,000price reductionacrossthe70indexsalesleftontheindexaftertheexecutionofthe manipulation is $1.9 million. Moreover, because new sales must fight the presumptionoflegitimacythatisaffordedtothepriorsalesatthemanipulated indexprice,theabilityofnewsalestosignificantlyraisetheindexbacktoits initialvalueisimpingedevenasthemanipulatedsalesfalloffoftheindexover time. This phenomenon was empirically verified for underwriter price stabilizationactivityforIPOs,whichwasfoundto“havealonglastingoreven permanenteffectonprices”(Lewellen,2006:632).

4.3. THE DETECTION OF MANIPULATIVE BEHAVIOR For a pricebased manipulation to be effective, the trigger must impact the pricemakingmechanismsuchthattheinformationconveyedisnotfilteredout asnoisenorsnuffedoutbytheweaklawoflargenumbersincontributingto the competitive equilibrium price (Hellwig, 1980:493). To detect manipulative behavior requires, therefore, the ability to screen for anomalous behavior againstthebackdropofmarketnoise,ataskforwhichstatisticalanalysesare particularly (though not exclusively) well suited (Pirrong, 1993, 2004). Because anomalies will also include legitimate transactions through which informed traders earn a return on their investments in gathering information, a presumption of legitimacy must attach to all open market trades as a null hypothesis. The burden then falls on the party alleging the manipulation to prove that the behavior in question rejected this hypothesis and thus fell outsideofthelevelofmarketnoiseassociatedwithlegitimacy.Thisburdencan onlybemetthroughproofthattheaccusedusedstrategicbehaviortocauseor attempt to cause a directional price movement, whether through one large anomaloustradeorthroughapatternoftradingexhibitedovertime. Theconstructionandcalibrationofsuchscreensneednotoccurinavacuum, asexamplesofsuccessfulscreeningmethodologiescanderivedirectlyfromthe

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 285 empirical studies discussed in Section 3. These studies use the law of large numbersaspresentedinthecentrallimittheorem,whichstatesthatthesumof a large number of independent random variables is approximately normally distributed.Fordatathatshouldbenormallyorlognormallydistributed(asthe returnsoncommoditiesoftenare),comparisonsofthedistributionofreturns forthemarketandforthesuspectedmanipulatorcanbeusedtotestthenull hypothesis that the behavior in question was legitimate. For example, Ruud relied on tests for skewness, kurtosis, and chisquare goodnessoffit to evaluatecomparativereturnsonIPOs,notingthat“thedistributionofoneday returnspeakssteeplyaroundzero,andthenegativetailofthedistributionis significantly curtailed” (Ruud, 1993:140). As price support was withdrawn, positiveskewnessandkurtosisinthedatadeclinedsuchthat: Thekurtosistestsfornormalityareconfirmedbychisquaregoodness offittests,whichfindthatthenullhypothesisofnormalityfortheone day, oneweek, twoweek, and threeweek distributions can all be rejected at the 1% level of significance. However, the null hypothesis thatthefourweekdistributionisnormalcannotberejected.Highinitial kurtosis that decreases as the holding period lengthens suggests that underwriters may at first intervene to support IPO prices and then withdrawtheirsupportovertime(Ruud,1993:146).

SimilarfindingsweremadebyLewellen(2006:625)andPrabhalaandPuri(1998:13) as to underwriter price support for IPOs, by Massa and Rehman (2008:302) in showing that affiliated funds change their holdings in the of firms borrowing from affiliated banks on the basis of privileged inside information, and by Golez and Marin (2012:31) concerning the price support by affiliates of parentbanks’stocksundertimesofeconomicstress. Inherent to all such analyses are the concerns of TypeI and Type II errors. Theseariseastheremaynotbeaonetoonemappingfromthebehavioralleged tocausethemanipulationtoademonstrableeffect,suchthatthescreensused cannot effectively distinguish between informed trading and manipulative behavior. Prevention of false positives requires robustness checks to confirm thatfindingsofanomalousbehaviorarenototherwisereadilyexplainable.These could include retesting the identified anomalies with different variable specificationstoexcludeotherpossibleinfluences(MassaandRehman,2008:301)or testing subsamples of the data to confirm the results (Golez and Marin, 2012:35; Lewellen,2006:643;PrabhalaandPuri,1998:19).Pragmatically,thiscanbeaccomplished for only a limited set of plausible alternative contingencies, as to require otherwise would place the party seeking to prove manipulation in the unacceptable position of having to disprove a relatively limitless number of

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 286 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 counterfactuals(Ledgerwood,2010:49).Givenpropervettingoffalsepositivesanda screeningmethodologyconsistentwiththenullhypothesisoftradelegitimacy, false negatives can then be mitigated by tailoring screens to detect specific behaviorofconcernforspecificcomponentsofthemanipulation. Separation of the manipulation’s pricemaking and pricetaking trades provides a logical foundation for determining the manipulation’s cause and effect,withdemonstrationofthenexusprovidingthelinkagebetweenthetwo. Proofofartificialpricethenbecomesasupportiveeffortthatisnotrequiredto provethemanipulationunderfraudbasedrules,butisnecessarytoprovethe manipulationundertheartificialpricestandardorforobtainingdisgorgement. 4.3.1. Establishing the Nexus Inmanymanipulationcases,proofofthenexusbetweenthetriggerandtarget is almost an afterthought because it refers to the same price. However, this pricecouldandlikelydoestietomanyotherpricesandpricetakingpositions thatextendacrossproducts,geographyandtime.Establishing(orrefuting)a causativenexusisthereforeessentialtomanipulationcases,asproofofanexus simultaneously demonstrates the intent and ability to manipulate, causation between trigger and target, and the linkage that enables the manipulative scheme to succeed. For a party seeking to prove the manipulation of a particulartargetedpositionbyagiventrigger,astatisticalanalysiswilloftenbe needed to demonstrate the direction, strength and reliability of the nexus asserted as causative. Practically speaking, this will foreclose from consideration many positions that were likely impacted by the manipulation, but for which insufficient proof of causation is shown. Likewise, a manipulation defense wishing to introduce evidence that incidental positions should be used to evaluate the net exposure of its portfolio to a directional price movement must also be prepared to demonstrate the strength and relevanceofanycausativenexuses. Analysisofasuspectednexusshouldevaluatetheselinkagesduringandapart from the times when manipulative behavior is suspected. Tighter linkages strengthen causation between pricemaking trades and pricetaking positions, asisoftenmagnifiedattimessuchassettlementwhenfixitiesinsupplyand demand emerge. Therefore, ex ante screening for such phenomena provides critical information as to the markets most in need of monitoring and surveillanceandastothetimes,instruments,andtradingbehaviorsofgreatest concern. This can assist the allocation of regulatory resources to serve their mostefficientuseandmaydirectthecoordinationofreportingrequirements withinandacrossregulatoryauthorities.Knowledgeofsuchoversightefforts willdetermanipulativebehavioratthetimesmostcriticaltopriceformation,

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 287 benefittingcompliantmarketparticipantsinthelongrunthroughtheincreased marketefficiencyderivedfrombettercertainty,improvedtransparency,greater liquidity,andreducedbidaskspreads. 4.3.2. Screening for Targets Any position thatderives its value from a price affected by a manipulation’s triggercouldtheoreticallyserveasatarget.Themanipulationisthenprofitable ifthesummedgaintothenetpositionheldacrossalltargetsaffectedbythe manipulation is leveraged sufficiently to exceed the manipulation’s costs, including any potential losses in the trigger. However, as we discussed in Section 3, it is possible that some of the positions that are targeted by the manipulationareunobservableexante,asmightoccurwithderivativespositions acquiredoffmarket.Likewise,evenforpositionsthatareknown,itispossible that the benefit derived is unquantifiable, as may occur if the manipulation benefitsqualitativetargetssuchasreputation,benefitstothirdparties,orcareer status. As reporting requirements increase under DoddFrank and as other agencies add transparency rules,42 the ability to proactively screen for manipulationtargetswillimprove,buttheabilitytoseeallpositionsmayremain elusive absentinvestmentsinlegaldiscovery.Theabsenceof effectivescreens leavesastheonlyrecoursecontinuedrelianceonexpostdiscoveryofpositions, oftenduetotheirextraordinarysuccess(asallegedwithETP,whichearnedlarge gainsasaresultofregionalgastransportationdisruptionscausedbytheimpact ofHurricaneRita)orspectacularfailure(aswithAmaranth,whichimplodedthe nextyearbyspeculatingonfuturehurricanesthatneverdeveloped). 4.3.3. Screening for Triggers Akeybenefitoftheframeworkisitsabilitytoaccommodatethethreetypesof behaviorthatcantriggerapricebasedmanipulation.Fromtheperspectiveof creatingadirectionalpricemovement,theonlydifferencebetweenthetriggers is their cheapness to the manipulator, with uneconomic trades incurring a positive cost, outright fraud incurring no cost (the fraud induces others to make the uneconomic trades), and the exercise of market power paying the manipulator (a negative cost). However, the screens needed to detect an exerciseofmarketpowerareexactlyoppositethoseusedtodetectuneconomic trading.ThisisillustratedinTable3.

42 For example, see FERC Enhancement of Electricity Market Surveillance and Analysis throughOngoingElectronicDeliveryofDatafromRegionalTransmissionOrganizationsand IndependentSystemOperators,137FERC¶ 61,066(October20,2011).

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 288 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

Table 3: Comparison of Screens for Market Power and Uneconomic Trading

Basis for Screen Market Power Screen Uneconomic Trading Screen

Price Relative to Cost* (Seller) P > MC* P < MC*

Price Relative to WTP** (Buyer) P < WTP** P > WTP**

Market Share and Concentration Both Generally High Focused on Price-Making Trades

Output Relative to Competition Below Above

Notes: * MC is Marginal Cost, which includes the opportunity costs of Seller’s next-best alternative. ** WTP is Willingness to Pay, as determined by the opportunity cost afforded by prevailing prices.

AcorporatecomplianceofficerlookingatTable3mightlaugh(orcry)atthe levelofclairvoyanceimpliedbythecombinedapplicationofthemarketpower anduneconomictradingscreens.Indeed,tradesthatdeviatefromcompetitive benchmarks seem destined for litigation and enforcement actions under antitrustprinciplesormarketmanipulationdoctrine,suchthatallpricemaking trades are continually analyzed under the crucible of thousands of potential plaintiffsandregulators.Thisisclearlyuntenable,astheoutcomewoulddrive liquidityfromthemarketsandchilllegitimatetrading. Deliverance from such overregulation derives from the requirement of anomalousnessthatsurroundsthenullhypothesisoftransactionallegitimacy. Thepartyseekingtoproveamanipulationmustdistinguishthebehaviorfrom thenoiseinthemarketanddemonstratethatthebehaviormotivated(andwas notmotivatedby)thesuspectedpricemovement–thusprovingtheintentto manipulate.Whilethefirsttaskisrelativelysimple,thesecondrequiresproof thattheallegedmanipulatordidnotactbaseduponanunobservableprivate informationset.Thisisnotanissuewhenmarketpoweristhetrigger,asthen themanipulator’sstandaloneselfinterestisalignedwiththedirectionalprice movementassociatedwiththemanipulation.Incontrast,proofofintentional uneconomic behavior requires an inescapably subjective determination that enough circumstantial evidence of losses incurred in the trigger exists to support the manipulation claim. Without more objective evidence – a “smokinggun”providedthroughvoicerecordings,instantmessages,emailsor whistleblower testimony – proof of manipulative intent using trading data alonemayprovedifficultatbest. One factor that should ease this burden is the character of uneconomic behaviorasaformoftransactionalfraud.Ifamarketparticipantisfoundto havecommittedoutrightfraudtocauseapricemovement,littledeferenceis given as to its private information set. Likewise, showing the participant to

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 289 haveintentionallyengagedinuneconomicbehaviortotriggerthemanipulation shoulddestroytheauraoflegitimacythatotherwisesurroundsitstransactions. Such anomalous behavior may be shown in the form of a pattern of price makingtradesthatappeartolosemoneyunabatedovertime(ETP,Amaranth, DiPlacido),orinonelargelossofamagnitudesufficientlyunusualtowarrant attention (as in the condominium example). By showing that the participant repeatedlyignoreditsopportunitycosts(inthecaseofapattern)orknowingly engaged in a tradethat accrued an unusually large loss, the likelihood that it wasactingonaprivateinformationsetgrowsincreasinglyunlikely.Whilesuch evidencemaynotremovealldoubtastowhetherthesuspectedbehaviorwas manipulative,atsomepointtheburdenofproofmustshiftfromtheaccuserto theaccusedunderanevidentiarystandardofapreponderanceoftheevidence. 4.3.4. Measuring an Artificial Price Under the fraudbased standard now shared by the CFTC, FERC, FTC and SEC, the need for proving an artificial price as a material element of a manipulationcaseisnolongeressential.Thatsaid,aninabilitytodemonstratea measurablepricemovementcausedbythetriggerraisesquestions(warranted ornot)astowhethertheactivitygaverisetoamanipulation,irrespectiveofthe strengthoftheotherelementsofthecase.Thedifficultyofcalculatingprice artificialityrestsinfindingtheappropriatecalculationofabutforcompetitive pricetoserveasthebenchmarkforthemanipulator’sopportunitycosts.The problemisthatthefirstpresenceofmanipulationinthemarketsetsinmotion a chain of actions and reactions that would neverhave unfolded butforthe manipulation,suchthattheresultingdataarepoisonedandthusunusablefor reconstructinganexactbutforprice.Thecalculationofanartificialpricethen must rely upon proxy benchmarks that (if contemporaneous with the manipulation) may also have been poisoned by the behavior or, if not, may raisequestionsastotheirsuitabilityasaproxy. Ifthepurposeofprovinganartificialpriceisforthecalculationofdisgorgement orsomeotherremedythatiscontingentontheamountofharmcausedbythe price movement associated with the manipulation, then precision is a primary consideration.However,ifthepurposeoftheartificialpricecalculationisonlyto confirmthe directionalityof the pricemovement caused by themanipulation’s trigger,the needforsuch precision is lessimportant.Inthese cases, it may be possibletomakeasimplershowingofthemanipulator’sdirectionalinfluenceon trading at the times the trigger was used. For example, if the manipulation involved trades contributed to an index to compute an average price, the poisonedindexdatamaybeexaminedwithandwithoutthemanipulator’strades to confirm directionality. This analysis would verify the directional effect these

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 290 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012 tradeshadontheindex,andmightalsoprovidearoughestimateoftheharm suchtradesinflictedpendingverificationthroughotherbenchmarks.

5. CONCLUSION Marketmanipulationremainsanunderstudiedandmisconstruedphenomenon, inpartduetolackofcohesivetheoryforanalyzingmanipulationacrosscases, agencies,statutes,andnow(withEUfinancialreform)continents.Inthispaper, wehavediscussedhowsuchanalyticalcontinuityispossibleifthecomponents of a pricebased manipulation are separated by cause (the trigger) and effect (thetarget),withademonstrablepricinglinkageestablishedbetweenthetwo (thenexus).TheresultinglogicoftheframeworkissummarizedinFigure4.

Figure 4: Summary of the Framework of Price-Based Market Manipulation

* Other types of manipulations could be analyzed using a nexus other than a price change. Logical continuity derives from the addition of uneconomic trading to the typesofbehaviorthatcantriggeramanipulation.Wecontendthatuneconomic bids and offers constitute transactional fraud, thus bridging the more traditionalanalysisofmanipulationcasesunderthestandardsofoutrightfraud or the creation of an artificial price by market power. Once the type of suspectedtriggerisshown,proofoftheremainderofthemanipulationfollows an equivalent logical path. This approach is consistent with existing statutes andwiththeacademicliteratureonthepoint. Note that we present Figure 4 not as a linear process, but as a loop. This anticipates that profits derived from one iteration of a manipulation may be reinvestedintothenext,suchthatprofitsareusedtobuildmoreleverageinto targeted positions and to add more financial heft to the next round’s manipulationtrigger.Thus,ascanoccurwithothertypesoffraudulentactivity,

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 291 themanipulatormaycontinuetogrowthesizeofthemanipulationunabated until detected either by embarrassing gains (as was alleged of ETP) or spectacular losses (Amaranth). Unlike other types of fraud, however, market manipulation is treated as a civil matter unless criminal elements such as conspiracy are present. Furthermore, the remedy often awarded for market manipulationisthedisgorgementofprofits,which(absentperfectdetection) provideslittledisincentiveforthebehavior.Civilpenaltiesthereforeremainthe primarydeterrenttomanipulativebehavior,withagenciessuchastheFERC combining such penalties with disgorgement and compliance plans to stem suchbehaviorperceivedunderitsjurisdiction.43 The historical precedent of manipulation cases tried before the CFTC, FERC, and SEC provide a patchwork of specific types of behaviors determinedtobeillegal,withnofunctionallinkagetoacommoneconomic logicacrossthecasestriedbyeachagency,muchlessacrossagencies.This“I knowitwhenIseeit”approachprovideslittleclearguidancetotradersasto the types of behavior that each commission perceives as manipulative, potentiallyleadingthemtoeitheravoidlegitimatetradestopreventsuspicion under uncertain enforcement standards or to pay no attention to such concernsgiventheagencies’historicaldifficultyinbringingsuchcases.As the U.S. and Europe implement broad antimanipulation rules, a more consistentandlogicalapproachtothedetectionandanalysisofmanipulation iswarranted.Tothispurpose,theframeworkweproposecouldclarifywhat doesanddoesnotconstitutemanipulationforbothmarketparticipantsand enforcement agencies. Such certainty would ultimately improve market efficiencythroughimprovingmarketliquidityandreducingbidaskspreads.

References Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale. 1992. “StockPrice Manipulation,” 5(3) Review of FinancialStudies503529. Aggarwal,Rajesh K.,and Guojun Wu. 2003.“Stock Market ManipulationTheory and Evidence,”presentedatthe64thAnnualMeetingoftheAmericanFinanceAssoc., http://www.afajof.org/pdfs/2004program/UPDF/P306_Asset_Pricing.pdf. Attari, Mukarram, Antonio S. Mello, and Martin E. Ruckes. 2005. “Arbitraging Arbitrageurs,”60(5)JournalofFinance24712511. Brunnermeier,MarkusK.,andLasseHejePedersen.2005.“PredatoryTrading,”60(4) JournalofFinance18251863.

43Forexample,sinceRule1ccameintoeffect,theFERChasleviedapproximately$300millionin civilpenalties,$151millionindisgorgementand$5millionincompulsorycomplianceplansasof June 2, 2012. These statistics are available at http://www.ferc.gov/enforcement/civil penalties/civilpenaltyaction.asp.

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 292 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

CFTC Release PR547108, “Energy Transfer Partners, L.P. and Three of Its Subsidiaries to Pay a $10 Million Penalty to Settle CFTC Action Alleging Attempted Manipulation of Natural Gas Prices” (March 17, 2008), http://www.cftc.gov/PressRoom/PressReleases/pr547108.html. Fama,EugeneF.1970.“EfficientCapitalMarkets:AReviewofTheoryandEmpirical Work,”25JournalofFinance383417. Fischel,DanielR.,andDavidJ.Ross.1991.“ShouldtheLawProhibit‘Manipulation’ inFinancialMarkets?”105HarvardLawReview503553. Gerard, Bruno, and Vikram Nanda. 1993. “Trading and Manipulation Around SeasonedEquityOfferings,”48(1)JournalofFinance213245. Goldstein, Itay, and Alexander Guembel. 2008. “Manipulation and the Allocational RoleofPrices,”75(1)ReviewofEconomicStudies133164. Golez, B., and J. Marin. 2012. “Price Support by BankAffiliated Mutual Funds,” http://papers:ssrn:com/abstractid=1652050. Grossman, Sanford J., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1980. “The Informational Role of Prices,”70AmericanEconomicReview393408. Hanson, Robin, and Ryan Oprea. 2009. “A Manipulator Can Aid Prediction Market Accuracy,”76Economica304314. Hellwig,M.1980.“OntheAggregationofInformationinCompetitiveMarkets,”22 JournalofEconomicTheory477498. Holley, David. 1996. “ExSumitomo Copper Trader Arrested,” Los Angeles Times, http://articles.latimes.com/19961023/business/fi56748_1_coppertrader. Jarrow,RobertA.1994.“DerivativeSecurityMarkets,MarketManipulation,andOption PricingTheory,”29(2)JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis241261. Kleit,AndrewN.2009.“IndexManipulation,theCFTC,andtheInanityofDiPlacido,” http://www.met.psu.edu/people/ank1/researchpapers/kleit.manipulation.pdf. Kumar, Paveen, and Duane J. Seppi. 1992. “Futures Manipulation with ‘Cash Settlement’,”47(4)JournalofFinance14851502. Kyle,AlbertS.,andS.Viswanathan.2008.“HowtoDefineIllegalPriceManipulation,” 98(2)AmericanEconomicReview274279. Ledgerwood, Shaun D. 2010. “Screens for the Detection of Manipulative Intent,” http://ssrn.com/abstract=1728473. ______andDanHarris.2012.“AComparisonofAntiManipulationRulesinUSand EU Electricity and Natural Gas Markets: A Proposal for a Common Standard,”33(1)EnergyLawJournal140. ______ and Wesley Heath. 2012. “Rummaging through the Bottom of Pandora’s Box: Funding Predatory Pricing through Contemporaneous Recoupment,” 6(3)VirginiaLawandBusinessReview509568. ______ and Johannes Pfeifenberger. 2012. “Using Virtual Bids to Manipulate the ValueofFinancialTransmissionRights,”http://ssrn.com/abstract=2050945. ______,GeraldTaylor,RomkaewBroehm,andDanielArthur.2011.“LosingMoneyto Increase Profits: A Proposed Framework for Defining Market Manipulation,” http://www.brattle.com/_documents/UploadLibrary/Upload919.pdf.

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 293

Lewellen, Katharina. 2006. “Risk, Reputation, and IPO Price Support,” 61 Journal of Finance613653. Massa, Massimo, and Zahid Rehman. 2008. “Information Flows Within Financial Conglomerates:EvidenceFromtheBanksMutualFundsRelation,”89Journal ofFinancialEconomics288306. O’Hara,Maureen.1995.MarketMicrostructureTheory.Oxford:Blackwell. Pirrong, Craig. 2010. “Energy Market Manipulation: Definition, Diagnosis, and Deterrence,”31(1)EnergyLawJournal120. ______. 2004. “Detecting Manipulation in Futures Markets: The Feruzzi Soybean Episode,”6(1)AmericanLawandEconomicsReview2871. ______. 1993. “Manipulation of the Commodity Futures Price Delivery Process,” 66(3)JournalofBusiness335369. Prabhala,N.R.,andManjuPuri.1998.“HowDoesUnderwriterPriceSupportAffect IPOs:EmpiricalEvidence,”http://ssrn.com/abstract=95948. RemarksofCommissionerBartChiltontoMetalsMarketInvestors,madeMarch23,2010 in Washington, D.C., http://www.cftc.gov/PressRoom/SpeechesTestimony/ CommissionerBartChilton/opachilton30.html. Ruud,Judith.1993.“UnderwriterPriceSupportandtheIPOUnderpricingPuzzle,”34 JournalofFinancialEconomics135151.

Cases Cited  Amaranth Advisors L.L.C., Order to Show Cause and Notice of Proposed Penalties, 120FERC¶61,085(July26,2007).  BrianHunter.130FERC¶63,004(2010).  BrianHunter.135FERC¶61,054(2011).  CFTCv.OptiverUS,LLCetal.,Case1:08cv06560LAP(S.D.N.Y.2012)  Consent Order of Permanent Injunction, Civil Monetary Penalty and Other Relief as to Defendants Amaranth Advisors, L.L.C. and Amaranth Advisors (Calgary) ULC, United States Commodity Futures Trading Commission v. Amaranth Advisors, L.L.C., et al., 07Civ.6682(DC)(S.D.N.Y.,August12,2009).  ConstellationEnergyCommoditiesGroup,Inc.,138FERC¶61,168(2012).  DiPlacidov.CFTC,2009U.S.App.LEXIS22692(2dCir.Oct.16,2009).  Energy Transfer Partners, L.P., et al., Order to Show Cause and Notice of Penalties, 120FERC¶61,086(July26,2007).  FERC Enforcement Staff Report: Findings of a NonPublic Investigation of Potential MarketManipulationbySuppliersintheNewYorkCityCapacityMarket,DocketNos. IN082000 & EL0739000 (February 28, 2008), http://www.ferc.gov/ enforcement/marketmanipulation/nyisoicap.pdf.  GFLAdvantageFund,Ltd.v.Colkitt,272F.3d189,205(2001).  FERC:InitialDecisioninDocketNo.IN0726004(January22,2010).

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM 294 / REVIEW OF LAW AND ECONOMICS 8:1, 2012

 In the Matter of: Anthony J. DiPlacido, Robert S. Kristufek, and William H. Taylor. http://www.cftc.gov/files/enf/01orders/enfavistacomplaint.pdf(Aug.21,2001).  InreDiPlacido,Comm.Fut.L.Rep.(CCH)P30,970(November5,2008).  IntheMatterofSumitomoCorporation,referencedinCFTCPressRelease#414498. http://www.cftc.gov/ogc/oporders98/ogcfsumitomo.htm(May11,1998).  Markowskiv.SEC,274F.3d525(D.C.Cir.2001).  Order Accepting Proposed Tariff Revisions Subject to Conditions, and Addressing Related Complaint,DocketNos.ER112875000andEL1120000,135FERC ¶61,022 (April12,2011).  OrderApprovingUncontestedSettlement,DocketNo.IN063003,128FERC¶61,269 (August31,2009).  Order Approving Uncontested Settlement, Docket Nos. IN0726000, IN0726003, IN0726004andIN0726005,128FERC¶61,154(August12,2009).  OrderonPaperHearingandOrderonRehearing,DocketNos.ER10787000,EL10 50000,EL1057000,ER10787004,EL1050002,andEL1057002,135FERC ¶ 61,029(April13,2011).  OrderonProposedRevisionstoInCityBuyerSideMitigationMeasures,DocketNo.ER10 3043000,133FERC¶61,178(November26,2010).  SEC v. Pawel Dynkowski et al., Case No. 09361 (May 20, 2009). http://www.sec.gov/litigation/complaints/2009/comp21053.pdf.  SECv.Masri,523F.Supp2nd361(S.D.N.Y.,2007).  United States Commodity Futures Trading Commission v. Amaranth Advisors, L.L.C., AmaranthAdvisors(Calgary)ULC,andBrianHunter,07Civ.6682(DC)(S.D.N.Y., May21,2007).  U.S.v.KeySpanCorp.,Case1:10cv01415WHP(S.D.N.Y.,February2,2011).  U.S.v.O'Hagan,521U.S.642,652(1997).

Regulations, Statutes and Tariffs CFTC Manipulation Rule, Prohibition on the Employment, or Attempted Employment, of ManipulativeandDeceptiveDevicesProhibitiononPriceManipulation,17C.F.R.Part 180(August15,2011). CommodityExchangeAct(CEA),7U.S.C.§§ 1etseq.[2010]. CouncilRegulation(EU)No1227/2011,OnWholesaleEnergyMarketIntegrityand Transparency,atart.2(4)(a),2011OJL326,1,6. DoddFrank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, P.L. No: 111203 (July21,2010). European Union Market Abuse Directive provision concerning market manipulation, Directive2003/6/ECoftheEuropeanParliamentandoftheCouncilof28January 2003oninsiderdealingandmarketmanipulation(marketabuse),OJL96,12.4.2003 (2006).(MAD).

Review of Law & Economics, © 2012 by De Gruyter

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM A Framework for the Analysis of Market Manipulation / 295

FERCAntiManipulationRule,18C.F.R.§1c,arisingundertheauthoritygrantedin15 U.S.C.§717c1and16U.S.C.§824v(a)asamendedbytheEnergyPolicyAct of2005,Pub.L.No.10958,119Stat.594etseq.(2005). FERCEnhancementofElectricityMarketSurveillanceandAnalysisthroughOngoing ElectronicDeliveryofDatafromRegionalTransmissionOrganizationsand IndependentSystemOperators,137FERC¶61,066(October20,2011). FERCPolicyStatementonEnforcement,113FERC¶61,068(October20,2005). FTCAntiManipulationRule,16C.F.R.Part317,arisingundertheauthoritygrantedin 42U.S.C.1730117305asamendedbySection811ofSubtitleBofTitleVIII ofTheEnergyIndependenceandSecurityActof2007(2009). PositionLimitsforFuturesandSwaps;FinalRuleandInterimFinalRule,17C.F.R. Parts1,150and151(2011). SECAntiManipulationRule,17C.F.R.§240.10b5,arisingundertheauthoritygranted in15U.S.C.§78j(b)(2010). SEC Exclusion for Price Support of IPOs, 15 U.S.C. §10(b) and 17 C.F.R. §240.l0b7 (1934), later recodified as Section 104 of Regulation M, 17 C.F.R. 242.104 (1996). ShermanAct§1,15U.S.C.§1etseq.(1890). StopTradingonCongressionalKnowledge(STOCK)Act,P.L.No:12t105(2012).

Authenticated | [email protected] Download Date | 12/11/12 9:24 PM