What Have We Learned About Disinflation?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

What Have We Learned About Disinflation? GEORGE L. PERRY BrookingsInstitution WhatHave We Learned about Disinflation? U.S. MONETARYPOLICY since 1979has been geared to stoppinginflation. It has had considerable success in doing so, but at a great cost in lost output and high unemployment, not only in the United States, but throughoutthe world. In Europeunemployment rose steadilyfrom 1979 to 1982 and is expected to rise further in 1983. In the United States, unemploymentrose to 10.7 percent at the troughof the recession in the fourthquarter of 1982,more than I1/2points above the previouspostwar recordreached at the worst point of the severe 1975recession. The durationof economic weakness in the presentdisinflation period distinguishesit from previous postwar recessions even more than the amountby which unemploymentrose and the level that unemployment reached. If the brief bounce-backin economic activity after mid-1980is ignored,the recent U.S. recession lasted twelve quarters.The previous postwar record was the five-quarterrecession of 1974-75. All other postwar recessions had lasted less than a year. By the end of 1983 the cumulativeexcess of unemploymentover its 1979level will be about 11 percentage point-years, correspondingto an estimated $700 billion to $900billion of forgone GNP in today's prices. This severe recession has been accompaniedby a dramaticslowing in the rate of inflation.Table 1 summarizesseveral measuresof inflation that reflect that slowdown, includingwidely used measures of actual inflationrates, which are affected by many special developments not closely associated with the underlying inflation problem, and some alternativemeasures of the underlyinginflation rate. Duringthe 1978- I thankJudith D. Kleinmanand PatriciaJ. Reganfor researchassistance. 587 (O 0 N TT'o C11 oo 1 (- (-o 0 o ooooo ~~0*.~0~0*. o-o t-- --oo ~o - 00 o., : 0 00 0 tr 06V ~ cl l (N0;; ~~00 mONOr?CN 10 _O .0~'~0O ON ONE o oo 0 ON -- 0S 000rO O. o cr NNooO FooooO O ON -- 0tNo -- - C ON oCo6o ~0 )-00 .00 0 0 3-~~~~~~~~~~~~~7 C ~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ci ci CN rl 00 00 0 73- 0 ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 3C Cu~ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~Z> - 73 0o0 CZ 0 0 ~ .0 ~ ~ ~ ~ z ~~~~~o > c Zou .Z w5 George L. Perry 589 80 perioda combinationof price increasesin food and energy (andrising interest rates as they affected the shelter component of the consumer price index) pushed the actual inflationrate to more than 10 percent, as measuredby any of the principalprice indexes shown in the top half of the table. In part because of the cessation or reversalof these develop- ments, these inflationrates slowed dramaticallyby 1982,and even more by the firsthalf of 1983. Both the accelerationof inflationand its subsequent slowdown are greatly attenuated in the measures of the underlying inflation rate displayedin the bottom half of the table. Nonetheless, the slowdown is still substantial,amounting to 4 to 5'/2 percentage points between the most inflationaryyear, 1980,and the firsthalf of 1983,using all measures except the volatile producerprice index, which has had a much larger swing. One important question raised by this experience is whether the disinflationthat has been accomplishedis more than might have been predicted on the basis of historical experience or whether it is about what would have been expected along with the huge recession that has occurred. The answer to this question, in turn, should shed some light on theoretical issues concerning how the economy works and on the options confrontingpolicymakers. In particular,a central issue to be consideredin light of the experienceof the past few years is whetherthe relation between output and inflationwill remainthe same when there has been a significantchange in the policy regime, such as that which occurredin the fall of 1979. Disinflation Policy and Inflation Models One model of the inflation process, the wage norm hypothesis, explicitly distinguishesbetween the cyclical variationin inflationand an ongoingnorm rate of wage increase aroundwhich the cyclical variation takes place.' Cyclical variationsin employmentand inflationare jointly determinedby the optimalresponse of firmsto variationsin the demand for their output. Althoughexpectations can, in principle,alter the wage 1. George L. Perry, "Inflationin Theory and Practice," BPEA, 1:1980,pp. 207-41; and Arthur M. Okun, Prices and Quantities: A Macroeconomic Analysis (Brookings Institution,1981). 590 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1983 norm, in practicethis hypothesis relates historicalchanges in the norm to experienced,rather than anticipated,changes in the economy. In a wage normequation, shifts in the norm, such as those that would arise from sustainedepisodes of inflationor economic slack, show up empiricallyas shiftsin the constantterm. The coefficientsrelating output and inflationin the short run are determinedby institutionaland behav- ioral characteristicsthat are largely unaffectedby changes in macroec- onomicpolicies or by changesin the wage normitself. In empiricalwork, I have modeled historicalnorms as stable except for occasional discon- tinuous shifts.2 Because wage norms do not respond in a linear or systematic way to any one measure of economic performance-for instance, they would respond less to a large spurt in the CPI coming from supply shocks (1978-80) than to an equivalentincrease in the CPI associated with a sustained period of very low unemployment(1966- 69)-I preferredthis procedureto moreelaborate ways one mightmodel norm shifts. It has providedan adequate, simplecharacterization of the past. For the present episode, this model predictedthat the policy aimed persistentlyat disinflationwould eventually shift the wage norm down- ward, but only after imposingunusually great or sustainedweakness in the real economy. Under these conditions, the wage norm equation would begin to exhibit forecast errorsindicating that wage norms were shiftingdownward. Most empirical studies of wage or price inflation have used past inflationrates, ratherthan the concept of wage norms, to help explain current inflation. The effect of lagged inflation in these models has generally been interpretedas representingthe influence of inflationary expectations on currentinflation, where these expectations are formed by an adaptiveprocess. In such models, developmentsaffecting inflation continue to have an influencelong after they occur. And the effect of a sustained shock affecting inflation grows with the passage of time. Because the laggedinflation terms directly embody long-runand expec- tational effects, a sustained macroeconomicpolicy change is not ex- pected to altereither the constantterm or the coefficientsof the equation relatingoutput and inflation. 2. Perry, "Inflationin Theory and Practice." CharlesSchultze found this character- izationof normchanges explained inflation throughout the peacetimeyears of this century. See CharlesL. Schultze, "Some MacroFoundations for MicroTheory," BPEA, 2:1981, pp. 521-76. George L. Perry 591 New classical models differ in importantrespects from either of the modelsjustdescribed. They rejectadaptive expectations as a description of how futureprice expectationsare formed.Generally they relatethese expectations to the policies that are anticipated,but that idea has never been implementedin a widely accepted way in a predictive equation. The problem is in determiningwhat economic agents expect policy to be and what amount of inflationthey think will accompany it. These models also hypothesize that marketsalways clear and that in doing so they incorporateexpected futureprices in an importantway. In the pure form of such models, levels of outputand employmentdeviate from full employment levels only because economic agents are mistaken about policy now and in the future. They interpret the very flat short-run Phillipscurve estimatedfrom historicaldata as a reflectionof mistakes by economic agents resultingfrom unpredictablepolicies. The central policy implicationof this theory is that policy should be steady and predictable,a prescriptionusually interpretedas supporting monetarism.According to the theory, the mistakes of economic agents would be minimized under such a policy and the short-runrelation between output and unemploymentwould become very steep. If the monetarypolicy changeof 1979was understoodas a changeto a steadier and more disinflationarypolicy regime, this theory predictedthat infla- tion would slow more promptly and output and employment would decline less than historicalequations would forecast. A version of this theory associated primarilywith William Fellner stresses the credibilityof policy in a more generalway.3 In this version, what matters is that policy convincingly promises it will not tolerate inflation,quite apartfrom precisely how policy is conductedin the short run. The credibilityhypothesis also anticipatedthat the change in policy regime in 1979, once widely believed, would bringdown inflationmore promptlyand with a smallerloss of outputand employmentthan would be predictedby empiricalmodels fit to historicalperiods. And further- more, it predicts that the coefficientsrelating output and inflationin the short run will change under a consistent policy, making the apparent Phillipscurve steeper. As these formulationssuggest, some of the important, distinctive predictionsof these alternativehypotheses could be tested only after a complete cycle of disinflationand subsequentrecovery, when it would 3. William Fellner, Towards a Reconstruction of Macroeconomics: Problems of Theory and Policy (American Enterprise Institute, 1976), pp. 116-18. 592
Recommended publications
  • Bessemer Trust a Closer Look Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World
    Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World A Closer Look. Debt Dynamics and Modern Monetary Theory in a Post COVID-19 World. In Brief. • U.S. and other developed economy debt levels are elevated relative to history, sparking questions over the sustainability of the debt and governments’ ability to continue spending to combat the economic impact of the novel coronavirus. • The U.S. post-crisis experience has the potential to differ from that of Japan’s after the 1990s banking crisis as a result of markedly different banking systems. JP Coviello • A post World War II style deleveraging in the U.S. seems less likely given growth Senior Investment dynamics; current labor, capital, productivity, and spending trends are obstacles to Strategist. such a swift deleveraging. • Unprecedented fiscal and monetary support in the wake of COVID-19 creates many questions about how governments can finance large spending programs over longer time horizons. • While the coordinated fiscal and monetary response to the crisis includes aspects of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), a full implementation remains unlikely. However, a review of the theory can be instructive in thinking about these issues and possible policy responses. Governments and central banks around the world have deployed massive amounts of stimulus in Peter Hayward an effort to cushion economies from the devastating effects of the COVID-19 pandemic. Clients, Assistant Portfolio understandably, are concerned about what this could imply over the longer term from a debt and Manager, Fixed Income. deficit perspective. While humanitarian issues are the top priority in a crisis, and spending more now likely means spending less in the future, the financing of these expansionary policies must be considered.
    [Show full text]
  • The Consumer Price Index and Index Number Purpose W
    1 THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX AND INDEX NUMBER PURPOSE W. Erwin Diewert, Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B. C., Canada, V6T 1Z1. Email: [email protected] Paper presented at the Fifth Meeting of the International Working Group on Price Indices (The Ottawa Group), Reykjavik, Iceland, August 25-27, 1999; Revised: September, 1999. 1. INTRODUCTION1 “What index numbers are ‘best’? Naturally much depends on the purpose in view.” Irving Fisher (1921; 533). A Consumer Price Index (CPI) is used for a multiplicity of purposes. Some of the more important uses are: · as a compensation index; i.e., as an escalator for payments of various kinds; · as a Cost of Living Index (COLI); i.e., as a measure of the relative cost of achieving the same standard of living (or utility level in the terminology of economics) when a consumer (or group of consumers) faces two different sets of prices; · as a consumption deflator; i.e., it is the price change component of the decomposition of a ratio of consumption expenditures pertaining to two periods into price and quantity change components; · as a measure of general inflation. The CPI’s constructed to serve purposes (ii) and (iii) above are generally based on the economic approach to index number theory. Examples of CPI’s constructed to serve purpose (iv) above are the harmonized indexes produced for the member states of the European Union and the new harmonized index of consumer prices for the euro area, which pertains to the 11 members of the European Union that will use a common currency (called Euroland in the popular press).
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation and the Business Cycle
    Inflation and the business cycle Michael McMahon Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 1 / 68 To Cover • Discuss the costs of inflation; • Investigate the relationship between money and inflation; • Introduce the Romer framework; • Discuss hyperinflations. • Shocks and the business cycle; • Monetary policy responses to business cycles. • Explain what the monetary transmission mechanism is; • Examine the link between inflation and GDP. Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 2 / 68 The Next Few Lectures Term structure, asset prices Exchange and capital rate market conditions Import prices Bank rate Net external demand CPI inflation Bank lending Monetary rates and credit Policy Asset purchase/ Corporate DGI conditions Framework sales demand loans Macro prudential Household policy demand deposits Inflation expectations Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 3 / 68 Inflation Definition Inflation is a sustained general rise in the price level in the economy. In reality we measure it using concepts such as: • Consumer Price Indices (CPI); • Producer Price Indices (PPI); • Deflators (GDP deflator, Consumption Expenditure Deflator) Money and Banking (5): Inflation & Bus. Cycle 4 / 68 Inflation: The Costs If all prices are rising at same rate, including wages and asset prices, what is the problem? • Information: Makes it harder to detect relative price changes and so hinders efficient operation of market; • Uncertainty: High inflation countries have very volatile inflation; • High inflation undermines role of money and encourages barter; • Growth - if inflation increases by 10%, reduce long term growth by 0.2% but only for countries with inflation higher than 15% (Barro); • Shoe leather costs/menu costs; • Interaction with tax system; • Because of fixed nominal contracts arbitrarily redistributes wealth; • Nominal contracts break down and long-term contracts avoided.
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. Working Paper The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: Karanassou, Marika; Sala, Héctor; Snower, Dennis J. (2007) : The evolution of inflation and unemployment: Explaining the roaring nineties, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 2900, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/4105 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu IZA DP No. 2900 The Evolution of Inflation and Unemployment: Explaining the Roaring Nineties Marika Karanassou Hector Sala Dennis J.
    [Show full text]
  • Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗†
    Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗† Martin S. Eichenbaum‡ Sergio Rebelo§ Mathias Trabandt¶ June 19, 2020 Abstract We analyze the e§ects of an epidemic in three standard macroeconomic models. We find that the neoclassical model does not rationalize the positive comovement of consumption and investment observed in recessions associated with an epidemic. Intro- ducing monopolistic competition into the neoclassical model remedies this shortcoming even when prices are completely flexible. Finally, sticky prices lead to a larger recession but do not fundamentally alter the predictions of the monopolistic competition model. JEL Classification: E1, I1, H0 Keywords: Epidemic, comovement, investment, recession. ∗We thank R. Anton Braun, Joao Guerreiro, Martín Harding, Laura Murphy, and Hannah Seidl for helpful comments. †Matlab/Dynare replication codes will be made available by the end of June 2020 at the following URL: https://sites.google.com/site/mathiastrabandt/home/research ‡Northwestern University and NBER. Address: Northwestern University, Department of Economics, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. §Northwestern University, NBER, and CEPR. Address: Northwestern University, Kellogg School of Man- agement, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. ¶Freie Universität Berlin, School of Business and Economics, Chair of Macroeconomics. Address: Boltz- mannstrasse 20, 14195 Berlin, Germany, German Institute for Economic Research (DIW) and Halle Institute for Economic Research (IWH), E-mail: [email protected]. 1Introduction Acentralfeatureofrecessionsisthepositivecomovementbetweenoutput,hoursworked, consumption, and investment. In this respect, the COVID-19 recession is not unique. At least since Barro and King (1984), it has been recognized that, absent aggregate productivity shocks, it is di¢cult for many models to generate comovement in macroeconomic aggregates.
    [Show full text]
  • The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond
    Working Paper No. 822 The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond by Riccardo Bellofiore* University of Bergamo December 2014 * [email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Co-principal investigators: Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute). The author thanks INET and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract An understanding of, and an intervention into, the present capitalist reality requires that we put together the insights of Karl Marx on labor, as well as those of Hyman Minsky on finance. The best way to do this is within a longer-term perspective, looking at the different stages through which capitalism evolves.
    [Show full text]
  • Burgernomics: a Big Mac Guide to Purchasing Power Parity
    Burgernomics: A Big Mac™ Guide to Purchasing Power Parity Michael R. Pakko and Patricia S. Pollard ne of the foundations of international The attractive feature of the Big Mac as an indi- economics is the theory of purchasing cator of PPP is its uniform composition. With few power parity (PPP), which states that price exceptions, the component ingredients of the Big O Mac are the same everywhere around the globe. levels in any two countries should be identical after converting prices into a common currency. As a (See the boxed insert, “Two All Chicken Patties?”) theoretical proposition, PPP has long served as the For that reason, the Big Mac serves as a convenient basis for theories of international price determina- market basket of goods through which the purchas- tion and the conditions under which international ing power of different currencies can be compared. markets adjust to attain long-term equilibrium. As As with broader measures, however, the Big Mac an empirical matter, however, PPP has been a more standard often fails to meet the demanding tests of elusive concept. PPP. In this article, we review the fundamental theory Applications and empirical tests of PPP often of PPP and describe some of the reasons why it refer to a broad “market basket” of goods that is might not be expected to hold as a practical matter. intended to be representative of consumer spending Throughout, we use the Big Mac data as an illustra- patterns. For example, a data set known as the Penn tive example. In the process, we also demonstrate World Tables (PWT) constructs measures of PPP for the value of the Big Mac sandwich as a palatable countries around the world using benchmark sur- measure of PPP.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]
  • Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019
    1 Harvard Kennedy School Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government Study Group, February 28, 2019 MMT (Modern Monetary Theory): What Is It and Can It Help? Paul Sheard, M-RCBG Senior Fellow, Harvard Kennedy School ([email protected]) What Is It? MMT is an approach to understanding/analyzing monetary and fiscal operations, and their economic and economic policy implications, that focuses on the fact that governments create money when they run a budget deficit (so they do not have to borrow in order to spend and cannot “run out” of money) and that pays close attention to the balance sheet mechanics of monetary and fiscal operations. Can It Help? Yes, because at a time in which the developed world appears to be “running out” of conventional monetary and fiscal policy ammunition, MMT casts a more optimistic and less constraining light on the ability of governments to stimulate aggregate demand and prevent deflation. Adopting an MMT lens, rather than being blinkered by the current conceptual and institutional orthodoxy, provides a much easier segue into the coordination of monetary and fiscal policy responses that will be needed in the next major economic downturn. Some context and background: - The current macroeconomic policy framework is based on a clear distinction between monetary and fiscal policy and assigns the primary role for “macroeconomic stabilization” (full employment and price stability and latterly usually financial stability) to an independent, technocratic central bank, which uses a “flexible inflation-targeting” framework. - Ten years after the Global Financial Crisis and Great Recession, major central banks are far from having been able to re-stock their monetary policy “ammunition,” government debt levels are high, and there is much hand- wringing about central banks being “the only game in town” and concern about how, from this starting point, central banks and fiscal authorities will be able to cope with another serious downturn.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: a Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey?
    Inflationary Expectations and the Costs of Disinflation: A Case for Costless Disinflation in Turkey? $0,,993 -44 : Abstract: This paper explores the output costs of a credible disinflationary program in Turkey. It is shown that a necessary condition for a costless disinflationary path is that the weight attached to future inflation in the formation of inflationary expectations exceeds 50 percent. Using quarterly data from 1980 - 2000, the estimate of the weight attached to future inflation is found to be consistent with a costless disinflation path. The paper also uses structural Vector Autoregressions (VAR) to explore the implications of stabilizing aggregate demand. The results of the structural VAR corroborate minimum output losses associated with disinflation. 1. INTRODUCTION Inflationary expectations and aggregate demand pressure are two important variables that influence inflation. It is recognized that reducing inflation through contractionary demand policies can involve significant reductions in output and employment relative to potential output. The empirical macroeconomics literature is replete with estimates of the so- called “sacrifice ratio,” the percentage cumulative loss of output due to a 1 percent reduction in inflation. It is well known that inflationary expectations play a significant role in any disinflation program. If inflationary expectations are adaptive (backward-looking), wage contracts would be set accordingly. If inflation drops unexpectedly, real wages rise increasing employment costs for employers. Employers would then cut back employment and production disrupting economic activity. If expectations are formed rationally (forward- 1 2 looking), any momentum in inflation must be due to the underlying macroeconomic policies. Sargent (1982) contends that the seeming inflation- output trade-off disappears when one adopts the rational expectations framework.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]