Independence, Propertylessness, and Basic Income Karl Widerquist

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

Georgetown University From the SelectedWorks of Karl Widerquist 2013 Freedom as the Power to Say No: Independence, Propertylessness, and Basic Income Karl Widerquist Available at: https://works.bepress.com/widerquist/90/ 1 Independence, Propertylessness, and Basic Income: A Theory of Freedom as the Power to Say No Karl Widerquist This is an early version of a prologue that was later published as: Karl Widerquist, March 2013. Independence, Propertylessness, and Basic Income: A Theory of Freedom as the Power to Say No, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, “Prologue,” pp. 1-8 Please cite the published version. Abstract The most difficult thing for a society to do is to avoid oppressing its most disadvantaged people. Yet many prominent theories of justice based on social contract or natural rights stress disadvantaged people’s responsibilities to the wider society as much or more than they stress society’s responsibility to them. This book begins an attempt to rectify that problem with a new theory of Freedom. The word, freedom, is commonly understood in two different ways: the absence of restriction, impediment, or interference (what I call scalar freedom) and the absence of slavery, detention, or oppression (what I call status or categorical freedom). This book argues that philosophers have focused too much on scalar freedom and proposes a theory of status freedom as “effective control self-ownership”—most simply, freedom as the power to say no. This book argues for and explores the implications of this theory of freedom. It shows that most societies today put the poor in situations in which they lack this crucial freedom, making them vulnerable to poverty, exploitation, and injustice despite other policies in place to help them. People who have no other option but to work for someone else to meet their basic needs are effectively forced laborers and are fundamentally unfree. The book argues that the basic income guarantee is an appropriate institution to help secure status freedom in a modern industrial society. 1 Table of Contents Prologue: The Big Casino 1. Introduction 2. Effective Control Self-Ownership: Freedom as the Power to Say No 3. Forty Acres and a Mule? Implications of Respecting Personal Independence 4. The Importance of Independence I: Framing the Issue 5. The Importance of Independence II: Freedom and Integrity 6. The Importance of Independence III: Market Vulnerability 7. What Good is a Theory of Freedom That Allows Forced Labor? Independence and Modern Theories of Freedom 8. If You’re an Egalitarian, Why Do You Want to Be the Boss of the Poor? Independence and Liberal-Egalitarian Theories of Justice 9. On Duty 10. Conclusion Preface and Acknowledgements I don’t know exactly when I began thinking about the ideas that made their way into this book. The general philosophical outlook is something that has been bouncing around in my head for some time. The outlook didn’t appear as a whole at any one point; it gradually developed. My interest in social justice began when I was a kid. My parents were politically interested, liberal Christians (a rarity these days). They, my brother, my sister, and I regularly discussed politics around the dinner table. Growing up in that context in the 1970s, I was optimistic about the progress the United States had made against racism, and I began to believe that the biggest remaining problem in most democratic countries is the horrible way we treat the poor. The television series, Free to Choose, by Milton Friedman, first introduced me to the 3 idea of a guaranteed income, which is now more commonly known as a basic income guarantee. He presented it mostly as a way to simplify the welfare system, but thinking about it over the years, I began to see it as the centerpiece of a just society and a serious challenge to the left: If we really care about other people in society, we should care about them unconditionally. The effort that has so far resulted in this book is a self-exploration of why I think this perspective is so important. As I see it, from the hanging gardens of Babylon to the modern sweatshop, one social problem occurs over and over again in different ways: advantaged people force disadvantaged people to serve them. I find the social contract answer extremely dissatisfying: it’s OK to force people to do things as long as you can imagine conditions under which they would have signed a contract subjecting themselves to force. For a time I thought I was a libertarian, but I eventually came to see the rightlibertarians, who call themselves “libertarians” in the United States, in a similar light as social contract theorists. They talk about freedom from force, but they invite everyone to ignore the tremendous amount of freedom-threatening force involved in the establishment and maintenance of property rights to the Earth and all its products. Without rectifying this issue, “libertarianism” becomes the defense of privilege at the expense of liberty. Although these issues were important to me, I didn’t do much direct work on social justice until the mid-1990s, when I taught several semesters of “the History of Economic Thought” at New York University while working on a Ph.D. in economics at the City University of New York. Some ideas from in-class discussions with students have probably made their way into this book. Also in the mid-90s, Michael Lewis, Pam Donovan, and I decided to have weekly breakfasts to talk about the progress we were making on our theses. These discussions usually turned to politics, 3 and one day we found the one thing we could all agree on was an unconditional basic income guarantee. So, Michael Lewis and I wrote a paper on it, which was eventually published (about ten years later and in revised form) as “An Efficiency Argument for the Basic Income Guarantee,” in International Journal of Environment, Workplace and Employment. One paper on the basic income guarantee led to another, as well as to involvement with the Basic Income Earth Network and to writing the Newsletter for the U.S. Basic Income Guarantee Network. I read a lot of impressive literature on basic income, but none of it quite seemed to articulate the reasons I thought it was so important. So, I had to explore my ideas more. In 2001, I was held a half-year fellowship at the Chaire Hoover at the Catholic University of Lovain in Belgium where Philippe Van Parijs was an influential mentor. By this time I realized that my interest in economics was secondary to my interest in social justice, and I decided that the best way to work fulltime on social justice was to go back to graduate school and get a doctorate in political theory. Getting a second doctorate still feels like a crazy idea, but in hindsight, it was the right thing for me. I started at Oxford in October of 2002, and by April of 2006, I completed a thesis entitled, Property and the Power to Say No: A Freedom-Based Argument for Basic Income. Many of the ideas in this book appeared first in that thesis—often in a slightly different form. My supervisor, Stuart White, gave me extremely helpful feedback on several versions of each chapter. Other faculty also gave me useful help and encouragement, including Dan McDermott (my substitute supervisor), Adam Swift and David Miller (my “transfer-of-status” examiners), Gerald A. Cohen (my internal thesis examiner) and Michael Otsuka (my external thesis examiner). 5 Some of the most valuable help I received was from discussing writings and ideas with my fellow graduate students at Oxford, both while we were students and since we left. These include Ayelet Banai, Ben Saunders, Christian Schemmel, Clare Heyward, John Filling, Katherine Eddy, Kieran Oberman, Miriam Ronzoni, Olly Dowlen, Omar Khan, Peter Balint, Rob Jubb, Sara Ababneh, Sarah Fine, Shlomi Segal, Steve Winter, Teun Dekker, Tiziana Torresi, and others. Other friends and colleagues have been helpful including Almaz Zelleke, Angela Cummine, Carole Pateman, Chris Brooke, Daniel Butt, David Casassas, Drew Chastain, Eri Noguchi, Gijs van Donselaar, Jason Berntsen, Jason Burke Murphy, Jeremy Koons, José Noguera, Julia Maskivker, Jurgen De Wispelaere, Marc-Andre Pigeon, Michael Howard, Michael Lewis, Nir Eyal, Pascal Couillard (who coined the term passive contribution), Paul Schumacher, Richard Caputo, Stephen Nathanson, Yannick Vanderborght, and many others. I have discussed these ideas with so many friends and colleagues that I can’t possibly name everyone who has influenced this book, and so I know when this comes out I’m going to owe apologies to several people. If I’ve discussed politics or philosophy with you in my lifetime, you might have influenced this book in some way. So, thanks. I received useful comments from participants at more conferences and seminars than I can name in Europe, North America, the Middle East, South Africa, and South America. For the most part, I don’t remember the name with the comment. But I do remember Peter Vallentyne asked a question that made me revise my definition of status freedom; Erik Olin Wright asked a question that made me reformulate a criticism of Nozick; and John Baker asked a question that made me realize I had to clarify all kinds of things about the relationship between this theory, liberal-egalitarianism, and the argument for a social responsibility to work. 5 I published four chapters of my thesis in the following journals: Public Reason, Human Rights Review, Political Studies, and Politics, Philosophy, and Economics. Although text from only one of these articles (the one in Human Rights Review) has made it into this book, anonymous referee comments from these (and other) journals made me think further about what this project ought to be.
Recommended publications
  • 9780748678662.Pdf

    9780748678662.Pdf

    PREHISTORIC MYTHS IN MODERN POLITICAL PHILOSOPHY 55200_Widerquist.indd200_Widerquist.indd i 225/11/165/11/16 110:320:32 AAMM 55200_Widerquist.indd200_Widerquist.indd iiii 225/11/165/11/16 110:320:32 AAMM PREHISTORIC MYTHS IN MODERN POLITICAL PHILOSOPHY Karl Widerquist and Grant S. McCall 55200_Widerquist.indd200_Widerquist.indd iiiiii 225/11/165/11/16 110:320:32 AAMM Edinburgh University Press is one of the leading university presses in the UK. We publish academic books and journals in our selected subject areas across the humanities and social sciences, combining cutting-edge scholarship with high editorial and production values to produce academic works of lasting importance. For more information visit our website: edinburghuniversitypress.com © Karl Widerquist and Grant S. McCall, 2017 Edinburgh University Press Ltd The Tun – Holyrood Road, 12(2f) Jackson’s Entry, Edinburgh EH8 8PJ Typeset in 11/13 Adobe Sabon by IDSUK (DataConnection) Ltd, and printed and bound in Great Britain by CPI Group (UK) Ltd, Croydon CR0 4YY A CIP record for this book is available from the British Library ISBN 978 0 7486 7866 2 (hardback) ISBN 978 0 7486 7867 9 (webready PDF) ISBN 978 0 7486 7869 3 (epub) The right of Karl Widerquist and Grant S. McCall to be identifi ed as the authors of this work has been asserted in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, and the Copyright and Related Rights Regulations 2003 (SI No. 2498). 55200_Widerquist.indd200_Widerquist.indd iivv 225/11/165/11/16 110:320:32 AAMM CONTENTS Preface vii Acknowledgments
  • Libertarianism Karl Widerquist, Georgetown University-Qatar

    Libertarianism Karl Widerquist, Georgetown University-Qatar

    Georgetown University From the SelectedWorks of Karl Widerquist 2008 Libertarianism Karl Widerquist, Georgetown University-Qatar Available at: https://works.bepress.com/widerquist/8/ Libertarianism distinct ideologies using the same label. Yet, they have a few commonalities. [233] [V1b-Edit] [Karl Widerquist] [] [w6728] Libertarian socialism: Libertarian socialists The word “libertarian” in the sense of the believe that all authority (government or combination of the word “liberty” and the private, dictatorial or democratic) is suffix “-ian” literally means “of or about inherently dangerous and possibly tyrannical. freedom.” It is an antonym of “authoritarian,” Some endorse the motto: where there is and the simplest dictionary definition is one authority, there is no freedom. who advocates liberty (Simpson and Weiner Libertarian socialism is also known as 1989). But the name “libertarianism” has “anarchism,” “libertarian communism,” and been adopted by several very different “anarchist communism,” It has a variety of political movements. Property rights offshoots including “anarcho-syndicalism,” advocates have popularized the association of which stresses worker control of enterprises the term with their ideology in the United and was very influential in Latin American States and to a lesser extent in other English- and in Spain in the 1930s (Rocker 1989 speaking countries. But they only began [1938]; Woodcock 1962); “feminist using the term in 1955 (Russell 1955). Before anarchism,” which stresses person freedoms that, and in most of the rest of the world (Brown 1993); and “eco-anarchism” today, the term has been associated almost (Bookchin 1997), which stresses community exclusively with leftists groups advocating control of the local economy and gives egalitarian property rights or even the libertarian socialism connection with Green abolition of private property, such as and environmental movements.
  • The Pursuit of Accord: Toward a Theory of Justice with a Second-Best Approach to the Insider-Outsider Problem

    The Pursuit of Accord: Toward a Theory of Justice with a Second-Best Approach to the Insider-Outsider Problem

    Georgetown University From the SelectedWorks of Karl Widerquist Fall 2019 The urP suit of Accord: Toward a Theory of Justice With a Second-Best Approach to the Insider- Outsider Problem Karl Widerquist Available at: https://works.bepress.com/widerquist/76/ The Pursuit of Accord: Toward a Theory of Justice With a Second-Best Approach to the Insider-Outsider Problem Karl Widerquist Georgetown University-Qatar [email protected] This is an early version of a paper that is now forthcoming in the journal Raisons Politiques (it should be out by the late spring). If you decide to cite or quote it, please refer to the published version if you can. The hardest thing for any society to do is to avoid oppressing its least advantaged individuals. If we fail to find a truly inclusive set of basic principles, the social structure is not a true social contract but an insider-outsider contract, the kind criticized by Carole Pateman and Charles Mills.1 One could say nearly the same thing about a set of natural rights that aren’t as natural and undeniable as their proponents would like to believe. Although the rights in the set might be universal in some sense, the set chosen favors a group of insiders. This article argues that most mainstream theories of justice offer first-best approaches to the insider-outsider problem. Although they have other second-best aspects, they presume that humans can create a basic social structure “that no one could reasonably reject.”2 This article argues to the contrary that no first-best solution to the insider-outsider problem exists.
  • Describe Catch 22 As Doc Daneeka Explains It

    Describe Catch 22 As Doc Daneeka Explains It

    Catch 22 Question Answers Describe Catch 22 as Doc Daneeka explains it. § It is a doctor’s duty to ground anyone who’s crazy. § BUT the doc cannot ground any pilot for reasons of insanity unless the pilot first asks him. § YET if a pilot asks to be grounded because he’s crazy, then he must be sane. Who doesn’t want to fight? § A soldier who doesn’t want to fight is sane (it’s impossible to want to fight). § Therefore, it’s impossible for a soldier to be excused from battle on the grounds of insanity. Describe the growth and expansion of M & M Enterprises. § This brainchild of Milo’s grows from a small operation into an international syndicate. § Within two weeks, Milo convinces Major de Coverley to name him mess officer and put squadron planes at his disposal for transactions and acquisitions. Milo’s ambition § As milo tries to get the best food for his mess hall and as he makes the best deals for the highest profit, his operations expand beyond the local level. § His operation becomes large enough to be considered a syndicate in which everyone supposedly has a share. Syndicate’s Success § Milo’s planes are everywhere. § Milo makes big deals all over the world. § Milo’s status at the head of the syndicate earns him respect-even fame- wherever he goes. § Mayor of Palermo § Assistant governor-general of Malta § Vice-shah of Oran § Caliph of Baghdad § Sheik of Araby Explain the significance of the character’s names. Yossarian § Colonel Cathcart’s reaction to the name suggests the trouble and rebellion we see in the character.
  • The Citizen's Basic Income As an Instrument to Help the Transition to Democracy

    The Citizen's Basic Income As an Instrument to Help the Transition to Democracy

    The Citizen’s Basic Income to Build Democracy and Justice Essay presented to NOPOOR Project in Paris, June 12 2012 1 Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy It is an honor for me to be invited to participate in this Kick-off Meeting of the NOPOOR Project, organized by the Development Institutions & Mondialization, DIAL, and the Institut de Recherche pour le Development, IRD, in Paris June 11th to 13th. It is, undoubtedly, a very relevant opportunity to exchange ideas about the experiences of so many countries, in the five continents, about how we can raise the level of justice in our societies, with freedom, by democratic means, so as to live with a sense of solidarity and peace. As a Brazilian Senator, member of the Workers’ Party (Partido dos Trabalhadores), author of Law 10.835/2004, that institutes a Citizen’s Basic Income to all residents of Brazil, including those foreigners who have lived in Brazil for five years or more, no matter the origin, race, sex, age or socioeconomic condition, and also Co-President of Honor of the Basic Income Earth Network – BIEN – I am happy to bring you information about what is going on in my country, and about the development of this proposal in other parts of the world. According to the law, approved by consensus of all parties, in December 2002 in the Federal Senate, and in December 2003, in the Chamber of Deputies, and then sanctioned by President Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva in January 8th, 2004, the Citizen’s Basic Income will be an annual monetary benefit, equal to all, sufficient to attend the basic needs of each person.
  • The Ethics and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee

    The Ethics and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee

    Georgetown University From the SelectedWorks of Karl Widerquist 2005 The thicE s and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee Karl Widerquist Michael Lewis Steven Pressman Available at: https://works.bepress.com/widerquist/9/ 1 The Ethics and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee This is an early version of a manuscript that was later published as: Karl Widerquist, Michael Anthony Lewis, and Steven Pressman (editors) The Ethics and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate, 2005 If you want to cite or quote it, please refer to the published version. If you have any questions, please contact me at: [email protected] v 2 The Ethics and Economics of the Basic Income Guarantee Contents List of Figures vii List of Tables viii List of Contributors x Preface xiii Acknowledgments 1 An Introduction to the Basic Income Guarantee 1 Michael Lewis, Steven Pressman, and Karl Widerquist Part One: History 2 In the Shadow of Speenhamland: Social Policy and the Old Poor Law 13 Fred Block and Margaret Somers 3 Inheritance and Equal Shares: Early American Views 55 John Cunliffe and Guido Erreygers 4 The Guaranteed Income Movement of the 1960s and 1970s 77 Robert Harris 5 A Retrospective on the Negative Income Tax Experiments: Looking 95 Back at the Most Innovate Field Studies in Social Policy Robert A. Levine, Harold Watts, Robinson Hollister, Walter Williams, Alice O’Connor, and Karl Widerquist Part Two: Debate 6 Basic Income in the United States: Redefining Citizenship in the 109 Liberal State Almaz Zelleke 7 Basic Income, Liberal Neutrality, Socialism, and Work 122 Michael W.
  • A Critical Analysis of Basic Income Experiments for Researchers, Policymakers, and Citizens Karl Widerquist

    A Critical Analysis of Basic Income Experiments for Researchers, Policymakers, and Citizens Karl Widerquist

    Georgetown University From the SelectedWorks of Karl Widerquist December, 2018 A Critical Analysis of Basic Income Experiments for Researchers, Policymakers, and Citizens Karl Widerquist Available at: https://works.bepress.com/widerquist/86/ PREVIEW: Because of publisher’s restrictions, I can only post a preview of this book. I hope it helps, if you need more info, contact me at [email protected] The Devil’s in the Caveats: A Critical Analysis of Basic Income Experiments for Researchers, Policymakers, and Citizens Karl Widerquist, Georgetown University-Qatar 1 Acknowledgments I would like to give special thanks to Zohaib Tahir, my research assistant, who provided incredibly useful help. I would also like to thank Misba Bhatti, Zahra Barbar, Mehran Kamrava, and everyone at CIRS for funding and organizing a workshop on this book, for funding my research assistant, for showing so much confidence in me, and for giving me a deadline to finish the first draft quickly. Thanks to the eleven people who came to the CIRS workshop and gave comments that made me rewrite this book all over again: Justin Gengler, Soumya Kapoor, John Gal, Simon Wigley, Jamie Cooke, Sarath Davala, Olli Kangasa, Loek Groot, Nisreen Salti, Mimi Ajzenstadt, and Robert Van der Veen. Thanks also to Kate McFarland, Ron Hikel, and Karsten Lieberkind for especially useful comments. Thanks to everyone who attended my various presentations of these ideas and gave me feedback, especially in the two small-group presentations I made a Georgetown-Qatar. 2 About the author Karl Widerquist holds doctorates in Political Theory and economics, but he is an Associate Professor of philosophy at Georgetown University-Qatar.
  • Michael C. Scoggins Joseph Heller's Combat Experiences in Catch-22

    Michael C. Scoggins Joseph Heller's Combat Experiences in Catch-22

    Michael C. Scoggins Joseph Heller’s Combat Experiences in Catch-22 n the forty-one years since the initial publication of Catch-22, Joseph Heller’s best-selling 1961 novel about World War II, the book has been a favorite subject for analysis and commentary, and an enormous bodyI of literary criticism on the work has been published. There have been numerous essays on the novel’s structure, its debt to other works of literature, its humor and logic, its moral and ethical values, and its religious themes and mythical overtones (Nagel 4). However, Heller’s treat- ment of the war itself has received scant attention by most critics. A few writers have compared Catch-22 to other war novels, especially the novels of Ernest Hemingway (Nolan 77-81; Aubrey 1-5), and David M. Craig has written two essays for War, Literature and the Arts demonstrating how Catch-22 incorporated some of Heller’s own combat experiences (Craig “Revisited,” 33-41; Craig “Avignon,” 27-54). But the majority of Heller’s crit- ics have taken the stance that Catch-22 has very little to do with World War II and is in fact not a war novel at all (Kiley and McDonald v; Merrill Joseph Heller, 11). Heller himself consistently minimized the war’s influence on the novel in many of his statements and interviews. For instance, in a 1970 speech in New York City, he told his audience that “Catch-22 is not really about World War II” (Heller “Translating,” 357), and in a 1975 interview he reiterated those sentiments: “As I’ve said, Catch-22 wasn’t really about World War Two.
  • Catch‐22 Reading Guide

    Catch‐22 Reading Guide

    Catch‐22 Reading Guide ‘Catch‐22 n. 1. a situation in which a person is frustrated by a paradoxical rule or set of circumstances that preclude any attempt to escape from them. 2 a situation in which any move that a person can make will lead to trouble (C20: from the title of a novel (1961) by J. Heller)’ (Collins) Synopsis Joseph Heller began work on Catch-22, the story of a US airman’s attempts to survive the madness of the Second World War, shortly after returning from the conflict himself. The son of Russian Jewish immigrants to the United States, Heller had joined the US Air Force in 1942 at the age of nineteen, going on to fly sixty bombing missions against enemy targets over southern Europe. After the war, while working as an advertising copywriter, he spent seven years writing a novel that reflected his experience, and what he saw as the insanity of military life. The book - which was originally titled Catch-18 - tells the story of Captain Joseph Yossarian, a member of a US bomber crew stationed on the Mediterranean island of Pianosa. Yossarian is convinced that the military is trying to get him killed, and that those around him are insane, and he spends the course of book trying to get out of flying any more seemingly suicidal missions. Yossarian is surrounded by a cast of bizarre characters, including Colonel Scheisskopf, who is obsessed with military parades at the expense of just about everything else, the newly promoted Major Major, Major, Major, who spends most of the war trying to hide from his men, and the profiteer Lieutenant Milo Minderbinder, a pure capitalist whose only ambition is to make money out of the war, and who ends up charging a commission on every military engagement.
  • Working Paper

    Working Paper

    New Perspectives on the Guaranteed Income Karl Widerquist Resident Research Associate The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Annandale-on-Hudson, NY, 12504-5000 914-758-7735 [email protected] INTRODUCTION The idea of a guaranteed income has been around in one form or another since Thomas Paine proposed a version of it in 1796 (Paine 1974). Except for a brief period in the 1960s and 1970s, it has not been a significant part of the public debate in the United States. However, interest in the guaranteed income is again growing; numerous articles and books have been written on the topic. Most of the recent interest has arisen in Europe but there has been some growing interest in the United States. Given the small number of guaranteed income supporters and the larger amount of literature on it, one wonder whether everyone who supports the idea has written a book on it. Be that as it may, growing interest in the guaranteed income makes this a good time for an assessment of some of the proposals that have recently been put forward. This paper discusses six books on the guaranteed income that have been published in the last decade: Arguing for Basic Income: Ethical Foundations for a Radical Reform edited by Philippe Van Parijs. 1992 Real Freedom for All: What (If Anything) Can Justify Capitalism? by Philippe Van Parijs. 1995 Public Economics in Action: The Basic Income/Flat Tax Proposal by A. B. Atkinson. 1995. The $30,000 Solution: A Guaranteed Annual Income for Every American By Robert R. Schutz.
  • Universal Basic Income Roundtable

    Universal Basic Income Roundtable

    The University of Maine DigitalCommons@UMaine Maine Policy Perspectives Margaret Chase Smith Policy Center 11-2019 Universal Basic Income Roundtable Daniel S. Soucier University of Maine, [email protected] Michael W. Howard Univerisity of Maine Dave Canarie [email protected] Philip Harvey Georg Arndt See next page for additional authors Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.library.umaine.edu/mcspc_perspectives Part of the Income Distribution Commons, and the Inequality and Stratification Commons Recommended Citation Soucier, Daniel S.; Howard, Michael W.; Canarie, Dave; Harvey, Philip; Arndt, Georg; Widerquist, Karl; Deprez, Luisa S.; and Zelleke, Almaz, "Universal Basic Income Roundtable" (2019). Maine Policy Perspectives. 1. https://digitalcommons.library.umaine.edu/mcspc_perspectives/1 This Book is brought to you for free and open access by DigitalCommons@UMaine. It has been accepted for inclusion in Maine Policy Perspectives by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@UMaine. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Authors Daniel S. Soucier, Michael W. Howard, Dave Canarie, Philip Harvey, Georg Arndt, Karl Widerquist, Luisa S. Deprez, and Almaz Zelleke This book is available at DigitalCommons@UMaine: https://digitalcommons.library.umaine.edu/mcspc_perspectives/ 1 Margaret Chase Smith Policy Center MAINE POLICY PERSPECTIVES Universal Basic Income Roundtable NOVEMBER 2019 MAINE POLICY PERSPECTIVES Universal Basic Income Roundtable Editor: Daniel Soucier Contributors: Michael W. Howard Dave Canarie Philip Harvey Georg Arndt and Karl Widerquist Luisa Deprez Almaz Zelleke Margaret Chase Smith Policy Center Since its founding in 1989, the Margaret Chase Smith Policy Center has engaged in applied public policy research and community engagement with the goal of improv- ing the quality of public discourse grounded in civility and a willingness to engage across political, social, and cultural differences.
  • WILLIAM STYRON and JOSEPH HELLER William

    WILLIAM STYRON and JOSEPH HELLER William

    r\c». ñ TRAGIC AND COMIC MODES IN TWENTIETH CENTURY AMERICAN LITERATURE: WILLIAM STYRON AND JOSEPH HELLER William Luttrell A Dissertation Submitted to the Graduate School of Bowling Green State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY June 1969 Approved by Doctoral Committee /»í J Adviser Dg$artment of English Graduate School Representative ABSTRACT William Styron and Joseph Heller are important contemporary American writers who can be associated with a certain "climate of opin­ ion" in the twentieth century. The intellectual basis for this climate of opinion is that the world we know today, metaphysically, historical­ ly, scientifically, and socially, is one that does not admit to a secure and stable interpretation. Within such a climate of opinion one hesi­ tates to enumerate metaphysical truths about the universe; one doubts historical eschatology, except perhaps in a diabolical sense; one speaks scientifically in terms of probability and the statistics of randomness rather than absolute order; and one analyzes social problems in terms of specific values in specific situations rather than from an unchanging and absolute frame of reference. Indeed, it is because of a diminishing hope of achieving an absolute or even satisfying control over the world that many have come to live with contingency as a way of life, and have little reason to believe that their partially articulated values rever­ berate much beyond themselves. Through their fictional characters William Styron and Joseph Heller are contemporary observers of this climate of opinion. Styron reveals in his novels a vision of man separated from his familiar values and unable to return to them.