Chapter 9 Solow

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Chapter 9 Solow Chapter 9 Solow O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics: a concise introduction O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 1 / 27 Overview 1 Introduction 2 Economic model 3 Computational implementation 4 Numerical results and simulation 5 Highlights 6 Main references O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 2 / 27 Introduction In 1956, Robert Solow published a seminal paper on economic growth and development. The proposed model, also known has the Solow–Swan, ignores some important aspects of macroeconomics, such as short-run fluctuations in employment, and makes several assumptions to describe the long-run path of the economy. It remains highly influential even today and despite its relative simplicity conveys a number of very useful insights about the dynamics of the growth process. It is also worth teaching from a methodological perspective. Numerical methods for solving differential equations will be introduced and the Euler method implemented to solve initial value problems (Dahlquist and Björck (2008) and Süli and Mayers (2003)). O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 3 / 27 Economic model This is a model of capital accumulation in a pure production economy. Countries produce and consume only a single, homogeneous good (output, GDP or real income). There are no prices because there is no need for money. Everyone works all the time, saves a fixed portion of income, invests and owns the firm (consumer side is not modelled). There is no government, thus no taxation nor subsidies. It is a closed economy model. This model captures the pure impact that savings (investment) has on the long-run standard of living (per capita income). The model is built around two equations: a production function and a capital accumulation equation. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 4 / 27 Economic model Production function The neoclassic production function is assumed to have the Cobb–Douglas form: α 1 α Y (t) = F(K (t); L(t)) = K (t) L(t) − (1) where K (t) is capital input, L(t) is labour input and α, between 0 and 1, is the capital share in production. This production function is neoclassic since it exhibits constant returns to scale, presents positive and diminishing marginal returns to factor accumulation, satisfies the Inada conditions. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 5 / 27 Economic model Production function In per capita terms, the production function (1) is: Y (t) K (t)αL(t)1 α = − , y(t) = k(t)α (2) L(t) L(t) Y (t) K (t) where y = L(t) and k(t) = L(t) From (1), taking logs and differentiating with respect to time on both sides, denoting by Y_ (t) and L_ (t) the derivatives of Y and L with respect to t, the results is Y_ (t) K_ (t) L_ (t) = α + (1 − α) : Y (t) K (t) L(t) The growth rate of per capita output is then simply y_ (t) k_ (t) = α : y(t) k(t) Thus, the source of increase in per capita output is the capital deepening. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 6 / 27 Economic model Capital accumulation The second key equation describes the path of capital accumulation K_ (t) = Y (t) − C(t) − δK (t) (3) i.e. the addition to the capital stock each period, K_ (t), depends positively on savings and negatively on depreciation, which takes place at rate δ. Since a fraction s of output is saved, Y (t) − C(t) = sY (t), the labour input L_ (t) grows at rate L(t) = n, the path of per capita capital accumulation is k_ (t) = sy(t) − (δ + n)k(t): (4) Thus, the change in per capita capital each period is determined by three terms: per capita investment, sy(t); per capita depreciation, δk(t); and population growth, nk(t). This is a differential equation and, for an initial stock of capital k0, it defines an initial value problem. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 7 / 27 Economic model Transitional dynamics: the Solow diagram The Solow diagram has two curves, plotted as functions of k(t), and can be used to understand per capita output evolves over time f(k) (δ+n)k consumption sf(k) investment k∗ Solow diagram O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 8 / 27 Economic model Transitional dynamics: the Solow diagram The curve y(t) = f (k(t)) = k(t)α is the production function, and the curve sy(t) = sk(t)α depicts the amount of per capita investment, which shifts y(t) down by the factor s. In turn, the line (δ + n)k(t) represents the amount of new per capita investment required to keep the amount of per capita capital constant. When the difference between the curve sy(t) and the line (δ + n)k(t) is positive (negative) the economy is increasing (decreasing) its per capita capital: capital deepening (widening) is occurring. when sy(t) = (n + δ)k(t), so that k_ (t) = 0, the amount of per capita capital remains constant, and such a point is a steady state. To sum up, we have the following. From the diagram it is found the steady-state value of per capita capital. Then, from the production function, the also constant steady-state value of output per worker is obtained. In turn, the steady state per capita consumption is given by the difference between steady state per capita values of output and investment. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 9 / 27 Economic model Steady state Since, in steady state, k_ (t) = 0, (4) and (2) can be used to solve the steady-state values of per capita capital and per capita output; thus, α α k_ (t) = sk(t) − (δ + n)k(t) ) 0 = sk ∗ − (δ + n)k ∗ and so the steady-state values are: 1 s 1−α k ∗ = (5) δ + n α s 1−α y ∗ = : (6) δ + n Ceteris paribus, countries that have high savings/investment rates will tend to be richer since they accumulate more per capita capital and, as a result, have more per capita output. In turn, countries that have high population growth rates will tend to be poorer. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 10 / 27 Economic model Golden rule The optimal capital accumulation leads to the golden rule savings rate that maximises the steady-state level of consumption. The per capita consumption c(t) is given by c(t) = (1 − s)y(t) and s can be y(t) c(t) written as s = y−(t) . _ At the steady state, k(t) = 0, that is, sy ∗ = (δ + n)k ∗. The latter can be written in terms of c(t), as c∗ = y ∗ − (δ + n)k ∗. dc To find k that maximises c, the first order condition, dk = 0, produces 1 α 1−α k gr = ; (7) δ + n gr considering A = 1. Note that k ∗ > k whenever s > α. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 11 / 27 Economic model Golden rule f(k) (δ+n)k sf(k) sgrf(k) gr k k∗ Golden rule savings rate O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 12 / 27 Economic model Linear approximation The Solow model has a closed solution and can be demonstrated that the convergence process is (globally) stable. Taking (4), considering k_ (t) = φ(k(t)), a first order Taylor approximation for k_ (t), being φ(k(t)) at least twice differentiable, is given by _ dφ(k(t)) k(t) ' φ(k ∗) + dk(t) jk ∗ (k(t) − k ∗) ' sf 0(k ∗) − (n + δ) (k(t) − k ∗) since φ(k ∗) = 0. _ _ Thus, whenever k(t) < k ∗ (k(t) > k ∗) then k(t) > 0 (k(t) < 0) and physical capital will accumulate (diminish) towards the steady state. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 13 / 27 Economic model Differential equation Since most differential equations are not analytically soluble, numerical solution of ordinary differential equations is a fundamental technique. A differential equation involves an unknown function, y(t), and its derivatives. A first–order ordinary differential equation, ODE, has the form dy y_ (t) = (t) = f (t; y(t)) (8) dt where f : R × R ! R and y(t):[t0; tT ] ⊂ R ! R. Equation (8) is non-autonomous but often economic problems are time-autonomous dy y_ (t) = (t) = f (y(t)): (9) dt The solution of (8) (or (9)) is a family of functions determined by a constant. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 14 / 27 Economic model Initial value problems A particular solution is computed by requiring that it goes through a specific point, the initial condition, (t0; y0 = y(t0)). The problem specified both by (8) (or (9)) and the initial condition is called an initial value problem, IVP. Solving the IVP is to predict the path that a quantity will take during a certain time interval, given the initial quantity. Problems involving ODEs of a higher order can be reduced to a system of first ODE equations by introducing new variables. Seldom do these equations have solutions that can be expressed in a closed form or the analytical form is often too cumbersome; solution techniques are generally unable to deal with large and nonlinear systems of equations that arise in real problems. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos Computational Economics 15 / 27 Economic model Initial value problems To solve a continuous problem in a computer, a discretisation process is required. Initial value problems can be numerically solved using finite difference methods and recursive procedures. The numerical procedures are based on approximations y0; y1; ··· ; yT to the exact solution y(t0); y(t1); ··· ; y(tT ) at the grid points: t0 < t1 < ··· < tT .
Recommended publications
  • Macroeconomic Overview of India
    Macroeconomic Overview of India Since India gained independence from the British in 1947, they have made steady progress in economic growth and poverty reduction. There has been political unrest and tension with Pakistan. However, there have not been substantial shocks to the economy. The most recent crisis was in 1991, but was not a major crisis when compared to Asia or Mexico. GDP did not decline in 1991 or 1992. Despite the political tensions, India has shown substantial growth in the very long run. India is one of the fastest growing economies in the world.1 Output has increased incrementally, poverty rates have been reduced, and there has been ongoing improvement in measures of human capital. Substantial challenges, such as ameliorating the persistence of poverty and insuring growth continues, still exists. Currently, India’s GDP is around $3-$4 trillion, per capita GDP around $3000. The GDP in India is growing at a rate of 8%. 2 By looking at the Solow Growth Model and some other key macroeconomics theories, some improvement can be done to improve these figures. Economic Policy Changes Government controls on foreign exports and investment have been reduced which provides an opportunity for continued growth. In 1991, the government implemented a number of reforms to liberalize the economy and integrate into the global market. These included currency devaluations and making currency partially convertible, reduced quantitative restrictions on imports, reduced import duties on capital goods, decreases in subsidies, liberalized interest rates, and tax reforms.3 The policy changes have resulted in a $200 million increase in Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) from 1991 to 1992.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 4 the Overlapping Generations (OG) Model
    Chapter 4 The overlapping generations (OG) model 4.1 The model Now we will briefly discuss a macroeconomic model which has most of the important features of the RA model, but one - people die. This small con- cession to reality will have a big impact on implications. Recall that the RA model had a few special characteristics: 1. An unique equilibrium exists. 2. The economy follows a deterministic path. 3. The equilibrium is Pareto efficient. The overlapping generations model will not always have these characteristics. So my presentation of this model will have two basic goals: to outline a model that appears frequency in the literature, and to use the model to illustrate some features that appear in other models and that some macroeconomists think are important to understanding business cycles. 1 2 CHAPTER 4. THE OVERLAPPING GENERATIONS (OG) MODEL 4.1.1 The model Time, information, and demography Discrete, indexed by t. In each period, one worker is born. The worker lives two periods, so there is always one young worker and one old worker. We’re going to assume for the time being that workers have perfect foresight, so we’ll dispense with the Et’s. Workers Each worker is identified with the period of her birth - we’ll call the worker born in period t “worker t”. Let c1,t be worker t’s consumption when young, and let c2,t+1 be her consumption when old. She only cares about her own consumption. Her utility is: Ut = u(c1,t) + βu(c2,t+1) (4.1) The worker is born with no capital or bond holdings.
    [Show full text]
  • Arxiv:1907.02155V1 [Econ.GN] 3 Jul 2019
    EMERGENT INEQUALITY AND ENDOGENOUS DYNAMICS IN A SIMPLE BEHAVIORAL MACROECONOMIC MODEL Yuki M. Asanoa,b,c, Jakob J. Kolbb,d, Jobst Heitzigb and J. Doyne Farmere,f,g,1 aDept. of Engineering Science, University of Oxford, OX1 3PJ, UK bFutureLab on Game Theory and Networks of Interacting Agents, Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research (PIK), PO Box 60 12 03, D-14412 Potsdam cFernUniversität in Hagen, Universitätsstraße 47, D-58097 Hagen dHumboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Unter den Linden 6, D-10099 Berlin eInstitute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, OX1 3UQ, UK fMathematical Institute, University of Oxford, OX2 6GG, UK gSanta Fe Institute, Santa Fe, 87501 NM, USA 1Corresponding author: [email protected] July 5, 2019 ABSTRACT Standard macroeconomic models assume that households are rational in the sense that they are per- fect utility maximizers, and explain economic dynamics in terms of shocks that drive the economy away from the stead-state. Here we build on a standard macroeconomic model in which a single rational representative household makes a savings decision of how much to consume or invest. In our model households are myopic boundedly rational heterogeneous agents embedded in a social network. From time to time each household updates its savings rate by copying the savings rate of its neighbor with the highest consumption. If the updating time is short, the economy is stuck in a poverty trap, but for longer updating times economic output approaches its optimal value, and we observe a critical transition to an economy with irregular endogenous oscillations in economic out- put, resembling a business cycle.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamic Efficiency in the Two-Sector Overlapping Generations Model
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 30 (2006) 1915–1936 www.elsevier.com/locate/jedc Dynamic efficiency in the two-sector overlapping generations model Emily T. Cremersà Department of Economics, National University of Singapore, Singapore 117570, Singapore Received 29 April 2004; accepted 31 May 2005 Available online 8 September 2005 Abstract This paper examines dynamic efficiency in the context of a two-sector overlapping generations model. First, conditions for dynamic efficiency in a centrally planned economy are derived. Then, in a competitive environment, the implications of dynamic (in)efficiency for the steady state relative price and steady state welfare are demonstrated. For the special case of a log-linear world, the golden rule savings rate is identified along with restrictions on parameters that yield dynamically efficient steady states. The results are further demonstrated via a welfare analysis of a simple tax/subsidy scheme. r 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: O41; E13; D9 Keywords: Dynamic efficiency; Two-sector; Overlapping generations 1. Introduction It has been known since Diamond (1965) that a competitive equilibrium in the one-sector overlapping generations (OG) model with productive capital may be dynamically inefficient,1 and by now it is equally well-known that the welfare effects ÃTel.: +65 6874 6832; fax: +65 6775 2646. E-mail address: [email protected]. 1In the one-sector neoclassical growth model, a steady state is said to be dynamically inefficient when a Pareto improvement is made possible via a reduction in capital accumulation. Galor and Ryder (1991) 0165-1889/$ - see front matter r 2005 Elsevier B.V.
    [Show full text]
  • How Discounting and Growth Can Be Good for the Environment
    How Discounting and Growth can be Good for the Environment Sjak Smulders* University of Calgary and Tilburg University This version: May 2007 Abstract It is often argued that discounting future utility imposes a threat on the conservation of the environment for future generations. The same holds for productivity growth. Discounting puts a lower weight on the future and reduces optimal investment levels, both investment in productive man-made capital and in environmental assets. Productivity growth might bias investment towards investment in man-made capital, thereby crowding out environmental investment. We will show that implicit in these arguments are assumptions about whether the environment is mainly a source of productive inputs (i.e., a productive asset) or a (direct) source of utility. It is shown that, in contrast to conventional arguments, if society cares enough about the environment (thus acting as a durable consumption good), higher discount rates may increase optimal levels of environmental quality. If society cares relative less about environmental amenities, growth stimulates investment in environmental quality if the rate of intertemporal substitution is high. This paper derives optimal investment rules in a neoclassical growth model with both man-made and environmental capital. We find that maximizing discounted utility may result in a level of environmental quality that exceeds the level that would be chosen when altruistically maximizing future generations' utility levels. SSRN areas: environmental economics, macroeconomics. Keywords: investment, growth, environment, discounting. JEL codes: O41, Q20. I would like to thank Lucas Bretschger, Reyer Gerlagh, Christian Groth, Cees Withagen and seminar participants at Copenhagen University for useful comments on an earlier version.
    [Show full text]
  • Problem Set 3 – Some Answers FE405
    Problem Set 3 – Some Answers FE405 1. Use the Discrete Time Ramsey equation and the Ramsey consumption function and explain what happens to the growth of consumption and to current consumption under the following circumstances: (a) a rise in the rate of interest (b) the individual becomes more impatient (c) the individual unexpectedly inherits a house ANSWER: a) A rise in the rate of interest (holding the discount rate constant and assuming for simplicity an initial situation of r = ρ) implies positive growth of consumption. In turn, this means a reduction in current consumption (the present value of wealth falls). b) If the individual’s discount rate goes up, consumption growth is negative. The individual wants to consume a larger share of their life-time income now so current consumption goes up. c) This will not affect the growth of consumption . i.e. the consumption path remains unchanged. However, it raises life-time wealth and hence consumption is higher now and in each subsequent period as compared with the situation before the unexpected windfall. The unexpected event increases permanent income and therefore consumption, there is going to be a jump up in consumption, to the new level consistent with the higher permanent income, when the event occurs. 2. What is precautionary saving? What assumptions are needed for precautionary savings to arise? Does precautionary saving resolve some empirical puzzles in consumption behavior? ANSWER: Precautionary savings are savings that are accumulated for a rainy day, a form of insurance against uncertainty. It requires the introduction of uncertainty (e.g. in health or labor income) and technically the third derivative of the utility function has to be positive so that the marginal utility of consumption is convex.
    [Show full text]
  • ECNS 502 Macroeconomic Theory Montana State University – Depart
    ECNS 502 Macroeconomic Theory Montana State University – Depart. of Ag. Econ. & Econ. Course Number 30020 Spring 2017 Course Packet Dr. Gilpin Course Schedule Term Paper Homework Week Date Topic Due Dates Due Dates 1 Jan 12 Syllabus & Lecture 1 2 17 Lecture 2 2 19 Lecture 3 & Lit. review guidelines 3 24 Lecture 3 con. Topic 3 26 SAS Module 1: Importing/exporting data 4 31 Lecture 3 con. 4 Feb 2 Lecture 3 con. 5 7 Lecture 4 Step 2 (references) 5 9 SAS Module 2: Cleaning data 6 14 Lecture 5 6 16 Lecture 5 con. 7 21 Lecture 5 con. 7 23 Lecture 5 con. 8 28 SAS Module 3: Merging data 8 Mar 2 Exam I: Lectures 1- 5 (LINH 306 – during class time) 9 7 Lecture 6 Step 3 (summaries) 9 9 Lecture 6 con. 10 14 Spring Break (no class) 10 16 Spring Break (no class) 11 21 Lecture 7 Step 4 (paper outline) 11 23 Lecture 7 con. 12 28 Lecture 8 12 30 Lecture 8 con. 13 Apr 4 Lecture 8 con. 13 6 Lecture 8 con. 1st draft of research paper 14 11 Lecture 9 14 13 Lecture 9 con. 15 18 Lecture 9 con. 15 20 Student Presentations Present research 16 25 Student Presentations Present research 16 27 Review for exam 17 May 1 Final Exam: Lectures 6 – 9 (LINH 406 2-3:50 pm) Final draft This page is intentionally left blank ECNS 502: Macroeconomic Theory Dr. Gilpin Table of Contents ______________________________________________________________________________ Syllabus ............................................................................................................................................ i Lecture 1: Introduction to Macroeconomics` ..................................................................................1
    [Show full text]
  • Alan Deardorffks Contributions on Trade and Growth!
    Alan Deardor¤’sContributions on Trade and Growth Gene M. Grossman Princeton University September 2009 To be presented at Comparative Advantage, Economic Growth, and the Gains from Trade and Globalization: A Festschrift in Honor of Alan V. Deardor¤, sponsored by the Department of Economics and the Ford School of Public Policy at the University of Michigan. The festschrift will be held at the University of Michigan on October 2-3, 2009. 1 1 Introduction It has been a pleasure to re-read some of Alan Deardor¤’spapers on trade and growth, and to read others for the …rst time. These papers are typical of Alan’s work; they artfully tease new insights on important issues from simple, familiar models. It is …tting to begin my review with “A Geometry of Growth and Trade.”Alan loves diagrams and given his skill in developing them, it is easy to see why. His diagrammatic analyses are as incisive as any algebraic treatment and more pleasing to the eye. Deardor¤ (1974) provides a simple geometric tool for analyzing trade and growth in a small open Solovian economy. Consider a small economy that produces a single consumer good and a single investment good from two factors of production, capital and labor. For simplicity, take the labor force as …xed.1 Suppose that households save a constant fraction s of income and that capital depreciates at constant rate . In Figure 1, R (p; K) represents the revenue or national-product function for an economy facing world relative price p of the consumer good and having a stock of capital K.
    [Show full text]
  • LECTURE 4 Douglas Hanley, University of Pittsburgh ECONOMIC GROWTH in THIS LECTURE
    INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS LECTURE 4 Douglas Hanley, University of Pittsburgh ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THIS LECTURE Why do countries grow economically? Why do some countries grow faster than others? Why has growth progressed at different rates over time? What is the best way to measure growth? OVERVIEW OF THE FACTS Growth in living standards was stagnant until about 1800 During this time, cross-country differences in living standards were small Since the industrial revolution, a subset of countries has experienced sustained per capita output growth of about 2% Because some countries did not experience this, cross- country differences in per capita output have increased GROWTH IN THE VERY LONG RUN POST INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION "THE GREAT DIVERGENCE" TWO MODELS OF GROWTH Malthusian Model Plausible and accurate for pre-1800 experience Features population growth and fixed supply of land Solow Model Applicable to post-1800 industry led growth Features growth in population, technology, and capital MALTHUSIAN MODEL THOMAS MALTHUS (1766-1834) CONCEPTUAL MOTIVATION We want to make a model of an agrarian society Low level of technological advancement No substantial capital investment No way to control birth or death rates Expect a pretty grim outcome THEORETICAL COMPONENTS Output is produced from land and labor C = Y = z ⋅ F(L, N) Population growth is a function of birth and death rates N ′ = N(1 + b − d) Assume this varies systematically with per capita income N ′ C = 1 + b − d = g N ( N ) CONTEMPORARY EVIDENCE Life expectancy rises strongly with output
    [Show full text]
  • An Overlapping Generational Model with Capital Accumulation in a Small Open Economy Walter Enders Iowa State University
    Economic Staff aP per Series Economics 1981 An Overlapping Generational Model With Capital Accumulation in a Small Open Economy Walter Enders Iowa State University Harvey E. Lapan Iowa State University Follow this and additional works at: http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_staffpapers Part of the Behavioral Economics Commons, Entrepreneurial and Small Business Operations Commons, and the Macroeconomics Commons Recommended Citation Enders, Walter and Lapan, Harvey E., "An Overlapping Generational Model With Capital Accumulation in a Small Open Economy" (1981). Economic Staff aP per Series. 69. http://lib.dr.iastate.edu/econ_las_staffpapers/69 This Report is brought to you for free and open access by the Economics at Iowa State University Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic Staff aP per Series by an authorized administrator of Iowa State University Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. An Overlapping Generational Model With Capital Accumulation in a Small Open Economy Abstract In this paper we develop a portfolio balance model which can be used to make an equitable comparison of alternative exchange rate regimes. Our point of departure from standard portfolio models is that we derive all asset demand functions from microeconomic behavior. As Helpman and Razin (1979) and Lapan and Enders (1980) have observed, all asset demand and expenditure functions used in a comparison of exchange rate systems must be consistent with individual optimizing behavior. This seemingly innocuous observation implies that many of the macroeconomic comparisons of fixed and flexible exchange rates are not legitimate. Inherent in any portfolio balance model is the implication that asset demand functions depend upon the joint distribution of asset yields.
    [Show full text]
  • Is the EU Structural Fund Creating Economic Growth? a Policy Analysis of the European Regional Development Fund - ERDF
    Is the EU Structural Fund Creating Economic Growth? A Policy Analysis of the European Regional Development Fund - ERDF Jonas Hallström Bachelor Thesis in Economics, 15 credits Economics C100:2 Spring term 2019 ABSTRACT The European Union uses a considered amount of the member states´ resources in the structural and cohesion funds to equalise income differences in the union and to induce growth to get economic cohesion between regions. An interesting and disputed question is if the funds are used in an effective way and if they reach their goals of economic growth. This is studied in the paper by a literature review and a following policy analysis which compare EU cohesion policy and academic knowledge. This question is addressed by performing a literature review of 16 articles about economic growth and its determinants in the European Union, and by comparing results from these studies with priorities of the main structural and cohesion fund’s policy, the investment priorities of European Regional Development Fund (ERDF). The paper concludes that seven out of 11 investment priorities correspond or fairly well correspond, to results from academic research of European growth. The study highlights the importance of the 11th investment priority, which is regional governments´ quality and its impact on the structural and cohesion funds´ growth efficiency. The paper also concludes that a well-adopted policy change would be to increase the status and importance of the 11th investment priority of the ERDF and the overall EU cohesion policy. Keywords: Structural and cohesion funds, EU regional growth policy, European economic growth, literature review, European regional development fund, policy analysis, growth efficiency, efficient allocation of EU funds, ERDF investment priorities.
    [Show full text]
  • ECON 581. the Solow Growth Model
    ECON 581. The Solow Growth Model Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko 1 / 59 General info e-mail: [email protected] office: HM Tory Building, 9-19 office hours: Friday 2{3 PM, or by appointment Teaching material available online web-page: http://www.artsrn.ualberta. ca/econweb/hryshko/ 2 / 59 General info Recommended text: Daron Acemoglu (2009). Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton University Press. But there're many other. Grading: an in-class midterm (35%) and final (45%) exams, and two problem sets (20%). 3 / 59 Scope of the course Growth (Solow model and models of endogenous growth) Consumption and savings Asset pricing Policy issues etc. 4 / 59 Outline for today Measures for standard of living The importance of economic growth Main long-run growth facts and their implications A basic model of long-run growth (the Solow model) Readings: Acemoglu, Chapters 1{3. 5 / 59 What is Economic Growth? Standard economists' answer: Growth in GDP per capita (or per worker), Y=L Does growth in per capita GDP reflect anything important about the improvement of living standards? {No consideration, for example, of the distribution of income within the economy (inequality) 6 / 59 Key Questions in Economic Growth Why are there countries so rich and others so poor? Why do growth rates vary across countries and over time? What are the policies that can change growth in the short and long run? Why do some countries \take off" while others fall behind 7 / 59 Measures of Living Standards Normally, the focus on two statistics of the average person's well-being: income and GDP per worker (productivity measure), and income and GDP per capita (welfare measure).
    [Show full text]